SciELO - Scientific Electronic Library Online

 
vol.11 issue2Nota del editorThe Export Performance and Innovation as a Strategy for Mexican SMES author indexsubject indexsearch form
Home Pagealphabetic serial listing  

Services on Demand

Journal

Article

Indicators

Related links

  • Have no similar articlesSimilars in SciELO

Share


Revista mexicana de economía y finanzas

On-line version ISSN 2448-6795Print version ISSN 1665-5346

Rev. mex. econ. finanz vol.11 n.2 Ciudad de México Jul./Sep. 2016

 

Artículos

Fashion with Snobs and Bandwagoners in a Three-Type Households and Three-Sector Neoclassical Growth Model

Representación del consumo: Modelo de Crecimiento Neoclásico con Tres Factores

Wei-Bin Zhanga  * 

a Ritsumeikan Asia Pacific University, Japan.


Abstract:

This study deals with interactions between fashion, economic growth and income and wealth distribution in a growth model of heterogeneous households with economic structure. The modelling of fashion and preference change is inspirited by the economic model of fashion recently published by Giovinazzo and Naimzada (2015). We introduce fashion consumption, fashion industry and preference change with regards to fashion goods into a general equilibrium dynamic growth model proposed by Zhang (2012, 2013). The economy consists of three groups of people (the snob, the bandwagoner, and the consumer) and three production (capital goods, consumer goods, and fashion) sectors. The motion of the economic system is described by a set of differential equations. For illustration, we simulate the motion of the economic system. We identify the existence of a unique stable equilibrium point. We also carry out comparative dynamic analysis. The comparative analyses provide some insights. into the complexity of economic growth with fashion.

JEL Classification: C23, G21, L2.

Keywords: Fashion; Snob; Bandwagoner; Fashion Industry; Neoclassical Growth Theory; Income and Wealth Distribution

Resumen:

El trabajo muestra las interacciones entre la moda, el crecimiento económico y la distribución del ingreso y la riqueza en un modelo de crecimiento de los hogares heterogéneos con la estructura económica. La modelación de la moda y la preferencia de cambio se basan en el modelo económico de la moda recientemente publicado por Giovinazzo y Naimzada (2015). Introducimos el consumo de moda, industria de la moda y el cambio de preferencias con respecto a los artículos de moda en un modelo de equilibrio general dinámico crecimiento propuesto por Zhang (2012, 2013). La economía se compone de tres grupos de personas (el snob, el bandwagoner, y el consumidor) y tres sectores de producción (bienes de capital, bienes de consumo y moda). El movimiento del sistema económico es descrito por un conjunto de ecuaciones diferenciales. Se simula el movimiento del sistema económico. Identificamos la existencia de un punto de equilibrio estable único. Finalmente llevamos a cabo análisis de dinámica comparativa el cual proporcionan algunas ideas sobre la complejidad de crecimiento económico considerando la moda.

Clasificación JEL: C23, G21, L2.

Palabras Clave : Moda; Esnob; Bandwagoner; Industria de la Moda; Modelo Neoclásico de Crecimiento; Distribución del Ingreso y la Riqueza

1. Introduction

Daniels (1951) describes: "Fashion is important because it is in almost everything." In modern times a fashion started in a metropolitan area in one country tends to rapidly globally spread over the world due to modern communications. Fashion has become a very important industry. According to Hemphill and Suk (2009: 1148), "It is the major output of a global business with annual U.S. sales of more than $200 billion - larger than those of books, movies, and music combined. (···). It has provided economic thought with a canonical example in theorizing about consumption and conformity. Social thinkers have long treated fashion as a window upon social class and social change. Cultural theorists have focused on fashion to reflect on symbolic meaning and social ideals." There are many studies about fashion and its interactions with other aspects of societies, even though the literature on formally modelling economics of fashion are not so many (e.g.,Pollak, 1976; Stigler and Becker, 1977; Abel, 1990; Karni and Schmeidler, 1990; Bianchi, 2002; Nakayama and Nakamura, 2004; Caulkins, et al., 2007; Zhou, et al., 2015). Simmel (1904) points out that fashion dynamics is enforced by common people's imitation of elite. Giovinazzo and Naimzada (2015) build a model to investigate the dynamics of the fashion cycle described by Simmel (1904). They argue that the originality of Simmel's thought has been lost in the modern literature on the subject. A main reason is that the... "models generally assume that preferences are exogenous and overlook the fact that individual tastes change in time, partly in line with choices previously made by the social group." Nevertheless, there are only a few formal economic models which explore dynamic complexity of fashion within context of economic growth and development theory. An analytical reason for this slow development is that how to deal with heterogeneity of goods and households with microeconomic foundation are still challenging issues in economics. The lacking of a proper analytical framework means that it is difficult for economists to deal with fashion and wealth accumulation in an integrated theory.

As far as fashion and classification of the population are concerned, this paper is inspirited by the economic model of fashion by Giovinazzo and Naimzada (2015). Their model is based on Benhabib and Day (1981). The population in their model is classed into the snob and the bandwagoner (Leibenstein, 1950). In their model there are one conspicuous good and one normal good. The bandwagoner's preference is characterized by that a particular kind of consumption increases in association with the rise in the social group's average consumption of the previous period. The snob's preference for a certain purchase falls with the rise of the average collective consumption of the preceding period. We use this idea to take account of fashionable behavior and their impact on macroeconomic as well as microeconomic variable in a general equilibrium dynamic model proposed by Zhang (2012, 2013). It should be remarked that Shi (1999) builds a wealth accumulation model with fashion and two groups of agents. Fashion is treated as an externality due to dependence of individual agents' time preference on the two groups' per-capita consumption habit. In Shi's approach stronger and more persistent fashion tends to generate oscillations in wealth. This study differs from Shi's approach in that Shi employs the traditional Ramsey approach to household behavior and this study uses Zhang's approach (Zhang, 1993, 2012). The paper is organized as follows. Section 2 develops the growth model of wealth and income distribution among heterogeneous households with fashion. Section 3 examines dynamic properties of the model and simulates the model with three groups. Section 4 carries out comparative dynamic analysis. Section 5 concludes the study.

2. The Basic Model

We consider an economic system consisting of fashion, capital goods, and consumer goods sectors. The capital goods and consumer goods sectors are the same as in the Uzawa two sector model (Uzawa, 1961; Burmeister and Dobell 1970; and Barro and Sala-i-Martin, 1995). Services are classified as consumer goods. The fashion sector produces fashion goods. It should be noted that it is straightforward to further classify fashion goods as durable and instantly consumed goods. For simplicity of analysis, we consider fashion goods as instantly consumed goods. Capital goods are be used as inputs in the three sectors. Capital depreciates at a constant exponential rate δk (0 < δk < 1) , which is independent of the manner of use. Households own assets of the economy and distribute their incomes to consume and save. Exchanges take place in perfectly competitive markets. Factor markets work well; factors are inelastically supplied and the available factors are fully utilized at every moment. Saving is undertaken only by households. All earnings of firms are distributed in the form of payments to factors of production, labor, managerial skill and capital ownership. Rather than classifying the population into the snob, the bandwagoner as in Giovinazzo and Naimzada (2015), we classify the population into the snob, the bandwagoner, and common consumer. The population consists of three groups, called consumers (who have no interest in fashion), the snob, and bandwagoner. Each group has a fixed population Ñj, indexed by j = C, S, B. Let prices be measured in terms of capital goods and the price of the commodity be unity. We denote the wage rates and rate of interest by wj(t) and r(t) respectively. Let pC(t) and pF(t) denote prices of consumer and fashion goods, respectively. The total capital stock K(t) is allocated between the three sectors. We use subscript index, i, s and f to stand for capital, consumer, and fashion goods sectors, respectively. We use Nm(t) and Km(t) to stand for the labor force and capital stocks employed by sector m. The total population Ñ and total qualified labor supply N are

N¯=N¯C+N¯S+N¯B,N=hCN¯C+hSN¯S+hBN¯B(1)

in which hj is the human capital of group j. The assumption of labor force being fully employed implies

Nit+Nst+Nft=N.(2)

2.1 The Capital Goods Sector

Let Fm(t) stand for the production function of sector m, m = i, s, f. The production function of capital goods sector is specified as follows

Fit=AiKiαitNiβit,αi,βi>0,αi+βi=1,(3)

where Ai, αi and βi are positive parameters. The marginal conditions for the capital goods sector are given by

r(t)+δk=αiFi(t)Ki(t),w(t)=βiFi(t)Ni(t),(4)

where wt is the wage rate of per qualified labor input. It should be noted that the wage rate of group j is

wjt=hjwt(5)

2.2 Consumer Goods and Fashion Goods Sectors

The production functions of the two sectors are

Fmt=AmKmαmtNmβmtαm+βm=1 αm βm>0,m=s,f,(6)

where Am, αm and βm are the technological parameters of the two sectors. The marginal conditions are

r(t)+δk=αmpm(t)Fm(t)Km(t),w(t)=βmpm(t)Fm(t)Nm(t)(7)

2.3 Current Income and Disposable Income

In this study, we use the approach to modeling behavior of households by Zhang (1993). Let k¯jt stand for per capita wealth of group j. We have k¯jt=K¯jt/N¯j where K¯jt is the total wealth held by group j. Per capita current income from the interest payment rtk¯jt and the wage income is

yjt=rtk¯jt+wjt.

The per capita disposable income is the sum of the current disposable income and the value of wealth. That is

y^jt=yjt+k¯jt.(8)

2.4 Budget Constraints with Fashion Goods

The disposable income is used for saving and consumption. The representative household from group j would distribute the total available budget between savings sj(t) consumer goods cj(t) and fashion goods fj(t). It should be noted fC(t) = 0. As far as no confusion occurs, we similarly use indexes without explicitly distinguishing groups. The budget constraints are

pCtcjt+sjt+pFtf¯jt=y^jt.(9)

2.5 Utility Functions with Fashion

We assume that utility level Uj(t) is dependent on cj(t), sj(t) and fj(t) as follows

Ujt=cjξj0ttsjλj0ttfjθj0tt,ξj0t,λj0t>0,θj0t0(10)

where ξj0(t), is the propensity to consume consumer goods, λj0(t) the propensity to save, and θj0(t) is group j's propensity to consume fashion goods (remark, θC0(t) = 0). Following Giovinazzo and Naimzada (2015), we consider the propensities of the snobs and the bandwagoners for consuming fashions endogenous. We will specify preference changes later on. It should be noted that although there are many heterogeneous-households growth models with endogenous wealth accumulation, the heterogeneity in most of those studies is by the differences in the initial endowments of wealth among different types of households rather than in preferences (see, for instance, Chatterjee, 1994; Caselli and Ventura, 2000; Maliar and Maliar, 2001; Penalosa and Turnovsky, 2006; and Turnovsky and Penalosa, 2006). Different households are essentially homogeneous in the sense that all the households have the same preference utility function in the approach.

2.6 Optimal Household Behavior

Maximizing the utility function subject to (9) yields

pCtcjt=ξjty^jtsjt=λjty^jtpFtfjt=θjty^jt,(11)

where

ξj(t)ρj(t)ξj0(t)λj(t)ρj(t)λj0(t)θj(t)ρj(t)θj0(t)ρj(t)1ξj0(t)+λj0(t)+θj0(t).

2.7 A Simplified Literature Review on Fashion Dynamics and Habit Formation

Before we specify how θS0(t) and θB0(t) change over time, we review the approach to fashion in discrete time accepted by Giovinazzo and Naimzada (2015). Their model is based on Benhabib and Day (1981). The population is classed into the snob and the bandwagoner, subscripted by i = SB. There are one conspicuous good and one normal good. The bandwagoner's preference is characterized by that a particular kind of consumption increases in association with the rise in the social group's average consumption of the previous period. The snob's preference for a certain purchase falls with the rise of the average collective consumption of the preceding period. The utility function is specified as

Ut=xiαittyi1-αitt(12)

where xi and yi are respectively the consumption levels of conspicuous good and normal good by i. The budgets with constant prices are

pxit+qyit=mit.(13)

It should be noted that price is fixed in the approach. As the model is partial (and for short-term problems), the fixed prices assumption is acceptable. The population is normalized unity. The population shares of the bandwagoners and the snobs are respectively w and 1 - w. The average conspicuous consumption of period t is

x¯t=ωxBt+1-ωxSt(14)

The snob's preference change is given by αSt=fSx¯t-1 where fSx¯t-1 is decreasing. The bandwagoner's preference change is given by αBt=fBx¯t-1 where fBx¯t-1 is increasing. It is straightforward to conduct dynamic analysis of the model with some specified preference change functions. As in Giovinazzo and Naimzada (2015), we define the average conspicuous consumption in time t as

f¯t=nfBt+1-nfSt,(15)

where

n=N¯BN¯B+N¯S.

Each individual takes the average behavior of large populations f¯t as given when he makes decision. Following Giovinazzo and Naimzada, we assume that the snobs' and the bandwagoners' propensities to consume fashions as follows

θjt=Λjf¯t,j=B,S.(16)

We also generally assume that θS(t) θB(t)) is decreasing (increasing) in f¯t As shown in the appendix, we can describe behavior of the model with any type of preference changes. It should be noted that fashion dynamics is a far more complicated phenomenon than we can accurately describe in one model. Hemphill and Suk (2009: 1148) describe this widely spread complex processes as follows, "People flock to ideas, styles, methods, and practices that seem new and exciting, and then eventually the intensity of that collective fascination subsides, when the newer and hence more exciting emerge on the scene. Participants of social practices that value innovation are driven to partake of what is "original," "cutting edge," "fresh," "leading," or "hot." But with time, those qualities are attributed to others, and another trend takes shape." In fact, there are different theories of fashion with regards to types of fashions. For instance, Miller et al. (1993) summarize types of models in theory of fashion developed more than two decades ago as follows: (i) external-individual models - aesthetic perceptions and learning model; (ii) external-social models - social conflict model, art movement model, ideas of beauty model, mass market model, market infrastructure model; (iii) internal-individual models - demand model, scarcity-rrarity model, conspicuous consumption model, individualism-centered model, conformity-centered model, uniqueness motivation model; (iv) internal-social models - trickle-down theory, collective behavior theory, adoption and diffusion model, symbolic communication model, subcultural leadership, model, spatial diffusion model, historical resurrection model, and historical continuity model. In our approach we use a highly aggregated variable called fashion good to describe fashion dynamics. This obviously can provide only limited insights into complexity of fashion dynamics.

2.8 Wealth Accumulation

According to the definition of sj(t) the change in the household's wealth is given by

k¯j̇t=sjt-k¯jt(17)

This equation states that the change in wealth is equal to saving minus dissaving.

2.9 Demand and Supply of the Three Sectors

The demand and supply equilibrium for the consumer goods sector is

cCtN¯C+cStN¯S+cBtN¯B=Fst.(18)

The demand and supply equilibrium for the fashion sector is

fStN¯S+fBtN¯B=Fft(19)

As output of the capital goods sector is equal to the depreciation of capital stock and the net savings, we have

St-Kt+δkKt=Fit(20)

where

S(t)sC(t)N¯C+sS(t)N¯S+sB(t)N¯B,K(t)=k¯C(t)N¯C+k¯S(t)N¯S+k¯B(t)N¯B

2.10 Capital being Fully Utilized

Total capital stock K(t) is allocated to the three sectors

Kit+Kst+Kft=Kt(21)

We completed the model. The model is structurally general in the sense that some well-known models in economics can be considered as its special cases. For instance, if the population is homogeneous and there is no fashion industry, our model is structurally similar to the neoclassical growth model by Solow (1956) and Uzawa (1961). It is structurally similar to the Walrasian general equilibrium model (note that in our approach the population can be classified into any number of groups) if the wealth is fixed and depreciation is neglected. The new aspect of this paper is the introduction of fashion into the general equilibrium growth model proposed by Zhang.

3. The Dynamics and its Properties

As the dynamic system is nonlinear and highly dimensional with wealth accumulation, it is difficult to get explicitly analytical properties. We can conduct simulation to follow the motion of the dynamic system. The following lemma shows that the dimension of the dynamical system is the same as the number of groups. We also provide a computational procedure for calculating all the variables at any point in time. First, we introduce a new variable z(t).

z(t)r(t)+δkw(t).(22)

3.1 Lemma

The motion of the economic system is determined by differential equations with z(t), k¯Bt and k¯St as the variables

z˙(t)=Λ~z(z(t),k¯B(t),k¯S(t)),k¯˙B(t)=Λ~z(z(t),k¯B(t),k¯S(t)),k¯˙S(t)=Λ~z(z(t),k¯B(t),k¯S(t)),(23)

in which Λ̃jt are unique functions of z(t), k¯Bt and k¯St defined in the appendix. At any point in time the other variables are unique functions of z(t), k¯Bt and k¯St determined by the following procedure: r(t) and wj(t) by (A2)→pC(t) and pF(t) by (A3) → f¯t by (A12)→ θj(t), ρj(t), ξj(t) and λj(t) by their definitions → k¯Ct by (A14) → y^t(t) by (A9) → K(t)=Jk¯j(t)N¯jcj(t),sj(t) and ft(t) by (10)→ wt(t) = w(t)/h1Kf(t) by (A5) → Ns(t) by (A7) → Ni(t) by (A6) → Kj(t) by (A1) → Fj(t)) by the definitions.

The lemma gives a computational procedure for following the motion of the economic system. We specify the preference changes as follows

θB0t=θ¯B+θ̃Bf¯t,θS0t=θ¯S-θ̃Sf¯t,(24)

where θ¯j and θ̃j are non-negative parameters. To satisfy this requirement, we have to specify how ξj0(t) and λj0(t) j = B, S are changed. We specify

ξB0(t)=ξ¯B-ωBθ~Bf¯(t)λB0(t)=λ¯B-(1-ωB)θ~Bf¯(t),0ωB1,ξS0(t)=ξ¯S+ωSθ~Sf¯(t)λS0(t)=λ¯S+(1-ωS)θ~Sf¯(t),0ωS1,(25)

where wB and wS are "weight" parameters. For instance, if wB is small, it simply implies that a change in the propensity to consume fashion is associated with a relatively small change in the propensity to consume consumer goods and a relatively large change in the propensity to save. Under (24) and (25) we have

ξj(t)ρjξj0(t)λj(t)ρjλj0(t)θj(t)=ρjθj0(t)ρj1ξ¯j+λ¯j+θ¯jj=B,S.(26)

We have that ρj(t) are constant. From (11) and (10) we have

f¯(t)=nρBθB0(t)y^B(t)pF(t)+(1-n)ρSθS0(t)y^S(t)pF(t),(27)

where we use (26). Inserting (24) in (27) yields.

f¯(t)=nθ¯BρBy^B(t)+(1-n)θ¯SρSy^S(t)pF(t)+(1-n)θ~SρSy^S(t)-nθ~BρBy^B(t)(28)

We specify parameter values as follows

Ai=1,As=1,Af=1.3,αi=0.31,αs=0.3,αf=0.36,δk=0.07,

NCNBNS=100102,hChBhS=126,λC0λB0λS0=0.80.90.95,

ξC0ξB0ξS0=0.150.110.1λ¯10λ¯20λ30=0.80.750.7,(29)

θ¯Bθ¯S=0.010.01 ,θ~Bθ~S=0.0010.001,ωBωS=0.50.5.

The population of the consumer is largest, while the population of the bandwagoner is the next. The capital goods and consumer goods sector's total productivities are respectively 1.3 and 1. We specify the values of the parameters, αj in the Cobb-Douglas productions for the capital goods and consumer goods sectors approximately equal to 0.3 (for instance, Miles and Scott, 2005; Abel et al., 2007). The depreciation rate of physical capital is specified at 0.05. A change in the propensity to consume fashion is associated with the equal changes (in the opposite direction) in the propensities to consume and to save. We specify the initial conditions as follows

z0=0.06,k¯20=10,k¯30=4.

The motion of the variables is plotted in Figure 1. In Figure 1, the national income is

Yt=Fit+pCtFst+pFtFft.(30)

Figure 1 The Motion of the of the Economic System 

Due to the fixed positions of the initial state, the national output and wealth/capital fall over time. The output level of the capital goods sector and fashion sector rise and the output level of the consumer goods sector fall overtime. The price of consumer goods falls. The rate of interest rises in association with falling wage rates. The prices of consumer goods and fashion goods and the propensities to consume fashion goods change slightly. Labor force is shifted from the consumer goods sector to the other two sectors. The capital input of the consumer goods sector is reduced and the capital inputs of the two other sectors are increased. The snob consume slightly less fashion goods and the bandwagoner more fashion goods. The average consumption level of fashion goods is increased over time. The snob consumes less consumer goods and has less wealth. The bandwagoner consumes more consumer goods and has more wealth. The consumer consumes less consumer goods and has less wealth.

Figure 1 shows that that all the variables become stationary in the long term. This implies the existence of an equilibrium point. The simulation confirms that the system has a unique equilibrium. We list the equilibrium values in (25)

Y=252,K=1061.7,Fi=74.28,Fs=181.24,Ff=5.5,f¯=0.46,wC=1.29,wB=2.58,wS=7.74,r=0.007,pC=0.96,pF=0.69,Ni=39.75,Ns=90.37,Nf=1.89,Ki=298.8,Ks=744.64,Kf=17.76,k¯C=7.15,k¯B=20.38,k¯S=71.34,cC=1.4,cB=2.59,cS=7.84,θB0=0.011,θS0=0.01,fB=0.343,fS=1.306

It is straightforward to calculate the three eigenvalues as follows

-0.15,-0.12,-0.10.

The eigenvalues are real and negative. The unique equilibrium is locally stable. This guarantees the validity of exercising comparative dynamic analysis.

4. Comparative Dynamic Analysis

We simulated the motion of the national economy under (29). It is significant to examine how the economic system reacts to exogenous changes. As the lemma provides the computational procedure to calibrate the motion of all the variables, it is straightforward to examine effects of change in any parameter on transitory processes as well stationary states of all the variables. We introduce a variable xj(t) which stands for the change rate of the variable, Δ¯xjt in percentage due to changes in the parameter value.

4.1 The Bandwagoner's Propensity to Consume Fashion Goods Being More strongly affected by the average fashion consumption

We now examine the effects that the bandwagoner's propensity to consume fashion goods is more strongly affected by the average fashion consumption as follows: θ̃B:0.0010.002 The bandwagoner's propensity to consume fashion goods is more sensitive to change in the average consumption. This implies that, for instance, if the snob consumes more fashion goods, the bandwagoner tend to consume more fashion goods with the same disposable income. The preference change brings about lower national income and wealth. The output levels of the capital goods and fashion goods sectors are augmented and the level of the consumer goods sector is reduced. The bandwagnoer's propensity to consume fashion goods is increased and the snob's propensity to consume fashion goods is reduced. The prices of the consumer and fashions are slightly increased. The rate of interest is rising in association with falling in wage rates. The average consumption of fashion goods is expanded. The bandwagoner consume more fashion goods and less consumer goods and have less wealth. The snob consume less fashion goods and more consumer goods and have more wealth. The consumer's behavior is slightly affected.

Figuer 2 The Bandwagoner's Propensity to Consume Fashion Goods Being more Strongly Affected 

4.2 The Snob's Propensity to Consume Fashion Goods being More Negatively affected by the Average Fashion Consumption

We now examine the effects that the snob's propensity to consume fashion goods is more negatively affected by the average fashion consumption as follows: θ̃S:0.0010.003 The change in the parameter implies that the snob's propensity to consume fashion goods is more sensitive to change in the average consumption. The average consumption level of fashion goods is reduced. This enhances the snob's propensity to consume fashion goods. The bradwagoner's propensity to consume fashion goods is lowered. The bandwagoner consume less fashion goods and more consumer goods and have more wealth. The snob consume more fashion goods and more consumer goods and have more wealth. The consumer consume more consumer goods and have more wealth. The preference change enhances national income and wealth. The output levels of the consumer goods and fashion goods sectors are augmented and the level of the capital goods sector is reduced. The prices of the consumer and fashions are slightly reduced. The rate of interest is reduced in association with raising in wage rates.

Figuer 3 The Snob's Propensity to Consume Fashion Goods Being more Negatively Affected 

4.3 The Bandwagoner's Propensity to Consume Fashion Goods Being Increased

We now examine the effects that the intercept in the function of the bandwagoner's propensity to consume fashion goods is increased as follows: θ¯B:0.010.015 If the average consumption level of fashion goods is kept constant, the change in the parameter implies a rise in the propensity to consume fashion goods. The snob's preference is slightly affected. The national output and wealth are reduced as the bandwagoner has stronger preference for fashion goods. The output of the fashion sector is increased and the output levels of the other two sectors are reduced. Labor force is shifted to the fashion sector from the other two sectors. The capital input of the fashion sector is augmented and the capital inputs of the other two sectors are reduced. The rate of interest is increased in tandem with falling in the wage rates. The prices of the consumer and fashions are slightly increased. The average consumption level of fashion goods is increased. The bandwagoner consume more fashion goods and less consumer goods and have less wealth. The snob consume less fashion goods and more consumer goods and have more wealth.

Figure 4 The Bandwagoner's Propensity to Consume Fashion Goods being Increased 

4.4 The Bandwagoner's Human Capital Being Improved

We now examine the effects that the bandwagoner's human capital is improved as follows: hB: 2 ⇒ 2.5 The total labor is augmented. Each sector employs more labor force. The national wealth and output are increased. All the three sectors' output levels and capital inputs are augmented. The bandwagoner's wage rate is increased and the other two groups' wage rates are slightly affected. The rate of interest and prices of the consumer and fashion goods are reduced. The bandwagoner's preference to consume fashion goods is increased and the snob's preference to consume fashion goods is reduced. The average consumption of fashion goods is expanded. The bandwagoner consume more fashion and consumer goods and have more wealth. The snob consume less fashion goods. The snob consume more consumer goods and have more wealth initially and consume less consumer goods and have less wealth in the long term. The consumer's behavior is slightly affected in the long term.

Figure 5 The Bandwagoner's Human Capital being Improved 

4.5 A Rise in the Bandwagoner's Population

We now examine the effects that the bandwagoner's population is expanded as follows: NB: 10 ⇒ 11 The total labor is augmented. Each sector employs more labor force. The national wealth and output are increased. All the three sectors' output levels and capital inputs are augmented. All the wage rates are enhanced. The rate of interest and prices of the consumer and fashion goods are reduced. The average consumption of fashion goods is expanded. The bandwagoner's preference to consume fashion goods is lowered and the snob's preference to consume fashion goods is enhanced. The bandwagoner consume more fashion and consumer goods and have more wealth. The snob consume less fashion goods. The snob consume more consumer goods and have more wealth initially and consume less consumer goods and have less wealth in the long term. The consumer's behavior is slightly affected in the long term.

Figure 6 A Rise in the Bandwagoner's Population 

4.6 A Rise in the Snob's Propensity to Save

We now examine the effects that the intercept of the function of the snob's propensity to save as follows: λ¯S:0.950.97 The national wealth and output are increased. The capital goods sector's output level and labor and capital inputs are augmented. All the wage rates are enhanced. The rate of interest and prices of the consumer and fashion goods are reduced. The average consumption of fashion goods is reduced initially and is slightly changed in the long term. The bandwagoner's preference to consume fashion goods is lowered initially and is almost not changed in the long term. The snob's preference to consume fashion goods is enhanced initially and is almost not changed in the long term. The bandwagoner's consumption behavior and wealth are almost not affected. In the long term the snob have more wealth and consume almost the same as before.

Figure 7 A Rise the Snob's Propensity to Save 

5. Concluding Remarks

This study dealt with interactions between fashion, economic growth and income and wealth distribution in an economic growth model of heterogeneous households with economic structure. The model emphasized the role of fashion on economic structural change and wealth and income distribution. It was inspirited by some ideas in the literature of economics of fashion. The model was developed within the framework of the integrated Walrasian general equilibrium and neoclassical growth theory by Zhang (2012, 2013). For illustration, we simulated the motion of the economic system. We identified the existence of a unique stable equilibrium point. We also carry out comparative dynamic analysis with regard to the snob's propensity to consume fashion goods, the bandwagoner's propensity to consume fashion goods, the bandwagoner's human capital, the bandwagoner's population, and the snob's propensity to save. We examined how changes in these parameters affect fashion development, wealth accumulation, and inequalities in income and wealth. From our simulation, we see that relations between fashion dynamics, inequality and economic growth are complicated in the sense that these relations are determined by interrelated in a very complicated manner. As our analytical framework is quite general, it is possible to generalize and extend the model in different aspects. One important direction is to introduce taxation into the general dynamic equilibrium model with fashion. We dealt with a simplified fashion dynamics. Fashion appears in arts, sciences, politics, academics, business, food, clothing, morality and entertainment in different forms and changes in different speeds. To analyze detailed structural changes within fashion industry in a macroeconomic framework with endogenous knowledge and wealth is a challenging issue in theoretical economics.

References

Abel, A.B. (1990). Asset Prices under Habit Formation and Catching up with the Joneses. American Economic Review, 80, pp.38-42. [ Links ]

Abel, A., Bernanke, B. S., Croushore, D. (2007). Macroeconomics,New Jersey: Prentice Hall. [ Links ]

Barro, R.J., X. Sala-i-Martin (1995). Economic Growth, New York: Mcgraw-Hill, Inc. [ Links ]

Benhabib, J., Day, R. (1981). Rational Choice and Erratic Behavior. Review Of Economic Studies, 48, pp.459-471. [ Links ]

Bianchi, M. (2002). Novelty, Preferences, and Fashion: When Goods are Unsettling. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 47(1), pp.1-18. [ Links ]

Burmeister, E., Dobell, A. R. (1970). Mathematical Theories of Economic Growth, London: Collier Macmillan Publishers. [ Links ]

Caselli, F., Ventura, J. (2000). A Representative Consumer Theory of Distribution. American Economic Review, 90, pp.909-26. [ Links ]

Caulkins, J. P., Hartl, R. F., Kort, P. M., Feichtinger, G. (2007). Explaining Fashion Cycles: Imitators Chasing Innovators in Product Space. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 31(5), pp.1535-56. [ Links ]

Chatterjee, S. (1994). Transitional Dynamics and the Distribution of Wealth in a Neoclassical Growth Model. Journal of Public Economics, 54, pp.97-119. [ Links ]

Daniels, A. H. (1951). Fashion Merchandising. Harvard Business Review, 29 (May), pp.51-60. [ Links ]

Hemphill, C. S., Suk, J. (2009). The Law, Culture, and Economics of Fashion. Stanford Law Review, 61(5), pp.1147-76. [ Links ]

Giovinazzo, V. D., Naimzada, A. (2015). A Model of Fashion: Endogenous Preferences in Social Interaction. Economic Modelling, 47, pp.12-17. [ Links ]

Karni, E., Schmeidler, D. (1990). Fixed Preferences and Changing Tastes. American Economic Review, 80, pp.262-273. [ Links ]

Leibenstein, H. (1950). Bandwagon, Snob, and Veblen Effects in the Theory of Consumers' Demand. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 64 (2), pp.183-207. [ Links ]

Maliar, L., Maliar, S. (2001). Heterogeneity in Capital and Skills in a Neoclassical Stochastic Growth Model. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 38, pp. 635-54. [ Links ]

Miles, D., Scott, A. (2005). Macroeconomics - Understanding the Wealth o Nations, Chichester: John Wiley& Sons, LTD. [ Links ]

Miller, C .M., McIntyre, S. H., Mantrala, M. K. (1993) Toward Formalizing Fashion Theory. Journal of Marketing Research, 30(2), pp.142-57. [ Links ]

Nakayama, S., Nakamura, Y. (2004). A Fashion Model with Social Interaction. Physica A: Statistical Mechanics and its Applications, 337 (3-4), pp.625-34. [ Links ]

Penalosa, C. G., Turnovsky, S. J. (2006). Growth and Income Inequality: A Canonical Model. Economic Theory, 28, pp.25-49. [ Links ]

Pollak, R. A. (1976). Habit Formation and Long-Run Utility Functions. Journal of Economic Theory, 13, pp.272-297. [ Links ]

Shi, S.Y. (1999). Fashion and Wealth Accumulation? Economic Theory, 14, pp.439-61. [ Links ]

Simmel, G. (1957). [1904] "Fashion", Reprinted In, The American Journal of Sociology, 62(6), pp.541-58. [ Links ]

Solow, R. (1956). A Contribution to The Theory of Growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics 70, pp.65-94. [ Links ]

Stigler, G. J., Becker, G. S. (1977). De Gustibus Non Est Disputandum. American Economic Review, 67, pp.76-96. [ Links ]

Turnovsky, S. J., Penalosa, C. G. (2006). Distributional Dynamics in a Neoclassical Growth Model: The Role of Elastic Labor Supply. Journal of Economic Dynamics & Control, 32, 1399-431. [ Links ]

Uzawa, H. (1961). On a Two-Sector Model of Economic Growth. Review of Economic Studies, 29, pp.47-70. [ Links ]

Zhang, W. B. (1993). Woman's Labor Participation and Economic Growth - Creativity, Knowledge Utilization and Family Preference. Economics Letters, 42, pp.105-10. [ Links ]

Zhang, W. B. (2012). Economic Growth with Heterogeneous Households, Gender Division of Labor, and Elastic Labor Supply. Journal of Income Distribution, 21, pp.15-37. [ Links ]

Zhang, W. B. (2013). A Synthesis of the Uzawa-Lucas Model with the Walrasian-General-Equilibrium and Neoclassical-Growth Theories. Economic Annals, 58, pp.8-38. [ Links ]

Zhou, E. F., Zhang, J. Z., Gou, Q, L., Liang, L. (2015). A two Period Pricing Model for new Fashion Style Launching Strategy. International Journal of Production Economics, 160 (February), pp.144-56. [ Links ]

Appendix: Proving the lemma

By (4) and (7), we obtain

zr+δkw=Niβ¯iKi=Nsβ¯sKs=Nfβ¯fKf(A1)

where β¯jβm/αm Insert (A1) in (4) and (5)

r=αrzβi-δk,wj=αwhjz-αi(A2)

where

αr=αiAiβ¯iβi,αw=βiAiβ¯i-αi.

Hence, we determine the rate of interest and the wage rates as functions of z. From (6) and (7), we have

pm=β¯mαmzαmwβmAm.(A3)

Insert pCcj=ξjy^j in (23)

ξCN¯Cy^C+ξBN¯By^B+ξSN¯Sy^S=wNsβs(A4)

where we use pCFs = wNs/βs Similarly for fashion goods we have

θBN¯By^B+θSN¯Sy^S=wNfβf.(A5)

Insert (A4) and (A5) in (2)

Ni=N^-n^y^C,(A6)

N^N-(θBβf+ξBβs)N¯By^B+(θSβf+ξSβs)N¯Sy^Sw,n^ξCβsN¯Cw.

Insert (A1) in (21)

zK=Niβ¯i+Nsβ¯s+Nfβ¯f.(A7)

Substituting (A4)-(A6) into (A7) yields

zK=N^1+n^1y^C,(A8)

where

N^1N^β¯i+ξBβsN¯By^B+ξSβsN¯Sy^Sβ¯sw+θBβfN¯By^B+θSβfN¯Sy^Sβ¯fwn^1ξCβsN¯Cβ¯sw-n^β¯i.

From the definitions of y^j we have

y^j=1+rk¯j+wj.(A9)

Insert (A9) in (A8)

zK=N^1+n^1wC+1+rn^1k¯C.(A10)

(A10) From (10) and (11), we have

f¯=nθB(f¯)y^BpF+(1-n)θS(f¯)y^SpF.(A11)

We assume that we can solve (A11) with f¯ as the variable as follows

f¯=f0z,k¯B,k¯S.(A12)

This implies that θj, ρj, ξj and λj can be treated as functions of zk¯B and

k¯S.

From (16) and (A10) we have

N^1+n^1wC+1+rn^1k¯C=zk¯CN¯C+zk¯SN¯S+zk¯BN¯B.(A13)

Solve (A13) with k¯C as the variable

k¯C=Λ(z,k¯B,k¯S)zk¯SN¯S+zk¯BN¯B-N^1-n^1wC(1+r)n^1-zN¯C.(A14)

It is straightforward to confirm that all the variables can be expressed as functions of z, k¯B , and k¯S , by the following procedure: r and wj by (A2) → pC and pF by (A3) → f¯ by (A12)→ θj, ρj, ξj and λj by their definitions → k¯C by (A14) → y^j by (A9) K=jk¯jN¯j cj, sj and fj by (10) → w = w1/h1Kf by (A5) → Ns by (A7) → Ni by (A6) → Kj by (A1) → Fj by the definitions. From this procedure, (A12) and (17), we have

k¯̇C=Λ̃Cz,k¯B,k¯SλCy^C-k¯C,(15)

k¯̇j=Λ̃jz,k¯B,k¯Sλjy^j-k¯j,j=B,S.(A16)

Taking derivatives of equation (A14) with respect to 𝑡 implies

k¯˙C=Λzz˙+Λ~BΛk¯B+Λ~CΛk¯C.(A17)

Here we don't give explicit expressions as they are tedious. Equal the two right-hand sides in (A15) and (A17)

z˙=Λ~z(z,k¯B,k¯S)(Λ~C-Λ~BΛk¯B-Λ~CΛk¯C)(Λz)-1.(A18)

The differential system (A16) and (A18) has variables z, k¯B and k¯S and consists of differential equations. In summary, we proved the lemma.

Received: September 29, 2015; Accepted: May 15, 2016

* Corresponding author: Ritsumeikan Asian Pacific University, 1-1 Jumonjibaru, Beppu-Shi, Oita-ken 874-8577 Phone 0977-78-1020, Fax 0977-78-1123. E-mail: wbz1@apu.ac.jp

Creative Commons License This is an open-access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License