SciELO - Scientific Electronic Library Online

 
vol.7 número4Método de diseño reducido para lagunas de estabilizaciónComparación de la resistencia horizontal y vertical contra el tizón tardío de la papa en Toluca índice de autoresíndice de materiabúsqueda de artículos
Home Pagelista alfabética de revistas  

Servicios Personalizados

Revista

Articulo

Indicadores

Links relacionados

  • No hay artículos similaresSimilares en SciELO

Compartir


Revista mexicana de ciencias agrícolas

versión impresa ISSN 2007-0934

Rev. Mex. Cienc. Agríc vol.7 no.4 Texcoco may./jun. 2016

 

Articles

Socioeconomic determinants of permanence of farmer in its production unit: Campeche, Mexico

José Antonio Ávila Dorantes1  § 

Reymundo Chan Chi2 

Ignacio Caamal Cahuich3 

Verna Grisell Pat Fernández3 

1 Centro Regional Universitario de la Península de Yucatán (CRUPY), Universidad Autónoma Chapingo (UACH), Exhacienda Temozón Norte, S/N. Domicilio Conocido, Municipio de Mérida, Yucatán. México. Tel/FAX. 01 (999) 924 00 54.

2 Estudiante del doctorado de la División de Ciencias Económico-Administrativas (DICEA), de la UACH. México. (econ_chan1980@hotmail.com).

3 DICEA, UACH. México. (pronisea02@yahoo.com.mx; gricelpat@hotmail.com).


Abstract:

The source of income is a critical variable. From the economic point of view, the decisions of the head of the family to stay or not in its production unit. Hence the objective: To evaluate the importance information 2010 of some socioeconomic variables, especially income in the decision of the head of marginalized family of Campeche, to stay or not in its production unit. Based on a model in which the producer wants to maximize their satisfaction, and this depends on income and rest, a model such as Logit, in which the dependent variable is (1) if the income obtained in the production unit develops it is greater than that obtained out, and (0) otherwise. They are considered as independent variables age, education, gender and family income. The results indicate that increased household income from marginal producer of the State of Campeche, is negatively correlated with the income earned within their production unit; however, the age of the household head positively acts.

Keywords: household head; income; marginal producers

Resumen:

El origen del ingreso es una variable fundamental, desde el punto de vista económico, en las decisiones del jefe de familia de permanecer o no en su unidad de producción. De aquí el objetivo: evaluar la importancia, con información de 2010, de algunas variables socioeconómicas, en especial del ingreso, en la decisión del jefe de familia marginado de Campeche, de permanecer o no en su unidad productiva. Partiendo de un modelo en el cual el productor quiere maximizar su satisfacción, y éste depende del ingreso y descanso, se desarrolla un modelo tipo Logit, en los cuales la variable dependiente es (1) si el ingreso que se obtiene en la unidad de producción es mayor al obtenido fuera, y (0) en caso contrario. Como variables independientes se consideran la edad, escolaridad, género e ingreso familiar. Los resultados indican que el aumento del ingreso familiar del productor marginal del Estado de Campeche, está correlacionado negativamente con los ingresos que obtiene dentro de su unidad de producción; sin embargo, la edad del jefe de familia actúa positivamente.

Palabras clave: ingreso; jefe de familia; productores marginales

Introduction

Market liberalization and trade liberalization in Mexico late last century, laid the foundation for the emergence of a competitive economy on the international market (De la Madrid, 1983; Salinas, 1989). As free market economy, prices are set by the marginal cost of the most inefficient company involved, so those who cannot be part, have to change to another market, or disappear as a company, (Nicholson, 2005). This means that companies have to be winners and losers, sectors also winners and losers. This caused displacement of labor and unemployment, when the sectors concerned not absorbed labor from the losers (Avila et al., 2008).

In the agricultural sector market liberalization and trade liberalization, only benefited large specialized producers, while the losers were in the small and medium producers; producers who have been, have responded by increasing production and yields to compensate for the decline in prices, the value of their production, and their income (Puyana and Romero, 2008); however, this response has not been widespread, and some of the producers and agricultural workers have emigrated to other sectors of the economy or abroad (López et al., 2011; Eliosa-Martínez, 2012) in relative terms the population employed in the agricultural sector has ebbed and occupied in the industrial sector and service (Cortez et al., 2008).

The source of income is a critical variable, from the economic point of view, the decisions of the head of the family to stay or not in its production unit. For example, small producers in three micro regions of the municipality of Oxchuc, Chiapas, due to their low yields, families supplement their income by planting cash crops and the provision of services (Roman and Hernandez, 2010). This income, in cash or in kind, should be enough for the family to meet their needs to which they are accustomed. When not reached, the head of the family tends to change its portfolio of income and undertakes new activities or deepens in others. On this point, Guzman, et al. (2005) found in Tepeji del Rio Hidalgo Mexico that rural income is no longer equivalent to farm income and rural families increasingly incorporate activities other than agriculture, as a way to compensate for low farm incomes. This income is formed from internal sources: the work of the head of the family, the couple, and the other members of the family nucleus (Yúnez and Naude, 2001; Lozano, 2003), and external and government or private subsidies. The work of the household head is developed in its production unit and beyond. Within its production unit behaves as a producer and can sometimes have employees, while outside it generally behaves as a wage earner in the labor market. To the extent that the head of household increases time employment in the labor market, lowers dedicated to its production unit. When this is the case, the production unit becomes directed generally by the couple, a family, rented, or in the worst case, abandoned.

In the marginal zone of the state of Campeche, which includes urban and rural producers who produce agricultural products or other, and are characterized by low income, live more than 210 thousand habitants which represent about 30% of the population entity (INEGI, 2010).

Given the agronomic and socioeconomic conditions of the state of Campeche, particularly the most marginalized area, agriculture that develops it is not competitive, among other reasons, because of the poor soil, the production system temporary lack of capital, technology among others; which result in low yields, poor quality agricultural products, and the difficulty of marketing them benefits the producer (Pat, 2010). In the city, small businesses often require other lines of work have to support themselves, to the ravages of companies have increased productivity and become more competitive. Both small (agricultural or not) producers need to diversify their incomes, for which see the need to supplement them with others obtained outside their production units. When this is the case, alternatives to get a good salary depends on several factors, including, socioeconomic are of interest to this study. Hence the objective to evaluate the importance of some socioeconomic variables, especially income in the decision of the head of marginalized family of Campeche, to stay or not in its production unit.

Theoretical and methodological framework

According to conventional economic theory, producers seek to maximize their well-being in the way they allocate their time considering the work and leisure (Nicholson, 2005). A key in determining the distribution of time is the wage rate in the labor market. The market wage rate is the opportunity cost or price of leisure. An individual will prefer to work less and enjoy more rest. No substitution effect in this act, there is only one effect of welfare. The decision of a producer is tripartite, choose between working on the farm, off-farm work or spend their leisure time (Ahearn et al., 2006).

As campechano small producer, the income derived from its production unit will reach not meet their needs and often used as a salaried looking outside their production unit. Your total income is the sum of income you get in your production unit and obtained outside it. However, household income consists of the income of the producer, the other members of the family, and subsidies received from the state. This family income that manages the household head is formed by joining, which has control, and the others mentioned, which may be considered external, because not depend on it.

If the economic welfare of a family for their spending on goods and services represented, and spending is equal to its income (Barro, 1993), the solution to the economic problem of the producer can be presented as follows:

Maximize U= f (Y, S) 1)

U= family welfare; f= function; Y= household income; and S= leisure.

The Y in turn consists of:

Y=Ye+Yp 2)

Ye= foreign income to the household head; Yp = income of the household head.

Ye= Yfi+Ys 3)

∑Yfi= sum of the income of other family members.

Ys= subsidies

Yp= Ypu + Ypf 4)

Ypu= producer income you get in your production unit; Ypf= income producer gets out of its production unit.

Ypu=piqi-rjqj 5)

∑piqi = total income from products derived from the production unit; ∑rjqj = total spending on inputs to make the products of the production unit.

Ypf= f(W) 6)

W= wage producer to work outside their production unit. Family income is formed by substituting in (2) to (3) and (4):

Y= (Yfi+Ys)+(Ypu+Ypf) 7)

Substituting in (7) to (5) and (6):

Y=(Yfi+Ys)+(piqi-rjqj)+f(W) 8)

When f(W) ≥ (∑piqi-∑rjqj) increases the likelihood that the producer tends to spend more time outside their production unit and the desire to abandon or give little attention incentive. This desire should increase in periods that are almost zero revenue production unit (for example, when a farmer temporary), because their time is divided between working on your production unit, outside, or rest to the point where the marginal value of each of these alternatives is equal, (Ahearn et al., 2006). Identify socioeconomic characteristics that are associated with f(W) ≥ ∑piqi-∑rjqj) is the interest of this work.

The formulation of models where the qualitative dependent variable is discrete dichotomous labor within the production unit or outside it, led to the development of Logit models, since what is needed is a probabilistic model that has two characteristics: 1) as more Xi, Pi = E(Y=1\X) also increases but never leave the range 0-1; and 2) the relationship between Pi and Xi is not linear; i.e., it approaches zero with increasing slower rates as Xi is reduced and approaches one with increasingly slower rates as Xi becomes very large.

The variables included in the models are:

Y= 1, If the income of the production unit is greater than the income you get out.

Y= 0, If the income of the production unit is less than the income you get out.

Gender of household head= dummy variable. 1 if you are male and 0 if female.

Head of household age= 19 years to 95 years.

Education of the household head= zero degrees of instruction to master level.

Monetary income= family in pesos.

In a Logit model it can be from the following function (Gujarati, 2009):

Pi=11+e-Zt=ez1+ez 9)

Where: Pi= probability that the head of household income generated in the production unit is greater than that obtained outside; e= base of the natural logarithm; and Zi= β1 + β2Xi.

In equation (10) represents what is known as a function of acumulative distribution logistics and satisfies the two requirements considered before. By meeting these requirements it creates an estimation problem, because Pi is nonlinear not only in X but also with the βs, which invalidates the usual procedure of ordinary least squares (MCO). This problem is solved by linearizing the equation. Therefore, you can write:

Pi1-Pi=1+eZi1+e-Zi=ezi 10)

Now Pi/(1 - Pi) is simply the odds ratio in favor of income from the production unit is greater than you would get out of it, the reason for the likelihood that a family get more income by working within of its production unit with respect to the probability is greater income earned outside. Thus if P= 0.6, means that the odds are 3 to 2 in favor of families earn more income within their production unit, that is, for every 10 families, 6 get more income within your business and 4 out of him. If the natural logarithm is taken of equation (10):

Li= β1 + β2Xi 11)

That is, L, the logarithm of the ratio of probabilities is not only linear in X, but also linear in the parameters βs. L is called Logit, hence the name logit model. It uses the method of maximum likelihood (MV) to estimate the parameters. The logit model in this case can be expressed as:

Li=1nPi1-Pi=β0+β1Genero+B2Edad+β3Esc+B4IngMon+u1 12)

Before the interpretation thereof, should consider the following general observations for model 1) since you are using the maximum likelihood method, which generally is a method for large samples, standard errors estimates are asymptotic; 2) as a result, instead of using statistical t to evaluate the statistical significance of a coefficient, the statistic is used (under the assumption of normal) x2. So that inferences are based on chi-square table. If the sample size is reasonably large, the t distribution converges to the normal distribution; 3) the conventional average of the goodness of fit, R2is not particularly significant for models with binary returned, like similar measures in R2, called pseudo R2(Gujarati, 2009). In models with binary returned, the goodness of fit is of secondary importance. What matters are the expected signs of the regression coefficients and their practical importance and/or statistics; and 4) to test the null hypothesis regarding all slope coefficients are simultaneously equal to zero, the equivalent of the F test in linear regression model is the statistic of the likelihood ratio (RV).

For the data of this research was used as the main tool, the National Survey of Income and Expenditure Survey (ENIGH) 2010 (INEGI, 2011), which provides a statistical overview of the performance of revenues and expenditures of households in terms of the amount, origin and distribution, associated with the characteristics of the homes themselves, their members and their homes. For handling the ENIGH the following tools that facilitated the interpretation of coded language of the survey they were used: catalog classification variables, description of databases, the interviewer manual construction of variables, the questionnaire and design sample.

The main databases and variables used for the state of Campeche were the basis of household data, the database Income, database Population and concentrated data base. The sample design for ENIGH 2010, is characterized by probabilistic; consequently, the results of the survey are generalized to the entire population. At the same time, the design is two-stage, stratified cluster where the last selection unit is housing and the observation unit is home. Subsequently a summary table where is concentrated the main variables of interest for the development and implementation of the model, such as monetary income, gender, age, transfers, education, among others, which conducted the analysis was developed and model fit.

As a final filter, the classification of the National Population Council (CONAPO) (CONAPO, 2010) the degree of municipal marginalization, in which the overall impact of the shortages suffered by the population as a result of lack of access to measured was used primary education, residence in inadequate housing, perceptions of low monetary income and income from the residence in small, scattered and isolated locations, such as the lack of health services, equipment and adequate infrastructure. a database was developed with surveys of households with degree of marginalization, occupying only households whose marginalization is "high" and "medium" (categories 2 and 3), since in the state of Campeche there is no marginalization very high (category 1), yielding a sample of 140 households. The software packages used were SAS and GRETL.

Results and discussion

According to the model set out above for the case of Logit for individual data was: Li= -1.6206 + 0.0274 gender + 0.0549 age + 0.0748 Esc - 0.00004 IngMon. As shown in Table 1.

Table 1 Results of regression to the state of Campeche processed data. Logit model. 

Número de obs = 140 LR Chi2(4)= 22.55 Prob > chi2 = 0.0002 Log likelihood= -162.165; McFadden R-Squared= 0.122101 *Significativa; Fuente: Elaboración propia con base en muestra obtenida del ENIGH 2010 y resultados del paquete SAS y GRETL.

The estimators of the model parameters are not marginal effects on both these models depend on the values taken by the explanatory variables. They can, therefore, be calculated marginal effects for each observation of the sample, obtaining the mean effects average of the individual effects. Alternatively, the marginal effects can be evaluated for the mean value of the explanatory variables. For large sample sizes, test the null hypothesis is accepted or rejected is based on the Wald statistic, which has a chi-square distribution. According to Table 1 the coefficients of the variables that are significant, different from zero, for a significance level of 0.05, plus the intercept, are age and monetary income. The regressor variables that had an impact on the exogenous variable were old and monetary income, while gender and schooling were not significant, according to the statistical likelihood ratio (RV) equal to 22.55 whose probability value was 0.0001 which is small and meaningful.

It is worth mentioning that in models with binary returned, the goodness of fit is not very important, are included for illustrative purposes only. What really matters are the expected signs of the regression coefficients and their practical importance and statistics. For the pseudo square R model used was the R square McFadden who was 0.1221.

The calculated equation Logit is used to obtain the probability that the income of the production unit are higher than those obtained outside it; applying this to a householder of male, with an average age of 56 years with an educational level of fourth grade, and average income of 20,488 pesos, the probability that the income of the production unit is greater than you would get out, is about 29%, suggesting that, with these characteristics, the producer would be encouraged to neglect its production unit. The size of family income acts negatively. As it increases, decreases the chances of that generated in the production unitis greater than you get out. This suggests that increases in household income are positively correlated with the increase in employment outside the production unit. This strategy can continue, while the expectations of the household head working out are preferable (Huffman, 1980).

The alternative of head of household employed outside the production unit is a frequent activity and corresponds to the strategy that has the head of the family to adapt to changes that occur in their levels of income and expense (Taylor et al., 1999). The income obtained by employed outside the production unit serves as a complement to that obtained inside. The problem that can be generated, is that the roles are reversed, and the supplementary income becomes the more important because the odds that the production unit becomes secondary activity increase, is rented, or abandoned (Contreras et al., 1992).

It is common to find householders in the elderly; however, they are not elderly, since the average is between 51 years. Age acts positively to revenue production unit tend to be higher than those obtained outside. It means that there is a tendency that the production units, agricultural or not, characterized by generating most of household expenditure, the activities are in the hands of householders elderly. This strategy allows the accumulated experiences over time can be used to better manage the production unit; however often in these units the income generated is laconic, householders in elderly are responsible for these activities because they have no alternative, and because their descendants migrate and send remittances to families (Taylor et al., 1999; Mora, 2004).

The schooling of heads of household is poor, on average did not finish primary in all deciles (Table 2). This variable is not significant in the model; however, in other studies (Huffman, 1980; Taylor, 2000) the importance of it in the form that affects the choices of families on the activities from which they derive income plus that this variable significantly related to rural home stands new sources of revenue including the work of migrants. The authors find that education has high yield income households, both in their agricultural activities and non-agricultural. They also find that, as education increases, the returns to education move to other than those related to crop production activities. These results indicate the wealth of taking into account the schooling variable, and analyze the conditions which must be included, because it seems to be an important element to explain the family income.

Table 2 Characteristics of heads of households by income levels. Deciles. Simple averages. 

Fuente: Datos elaborados en base a la muestra extraída de la ENIGH, 2010

The gender variable is not significant in the models, and except for some deciles (Table 2), seems to be generalized to men who are heads of households trend. According to the model, if the household head is male or female, no influence to explain why household income is greater in the production unit outside.

Conclusions

Over time has been normal for marginal producers (agricultural or not), supplement their expenses with income from work performed outside their production unit, as traditional strategy to changes in income, prices and wages that are presented in their environment. However, this study indicates that increased household income from marginal producer in the state of Campeche, is positively correlated with the income earned outside their production unit, so it could be a weight ratio of the gradual change of activity master of the household head, relegating the original to a secondary activity, renting its production unit, or even deserting.

Work also indicates that the age of the household head positively acts to revenue production unit are greater than those obtained outside. Since these householders are not elderly, on average, you can use this feature to the new momentum of its original activities, supporting avoid migrating to these householders to illusory poles of development where they are integrated as unemployed, underemployed and with minimum social benefits. The financial support from the rest of the family and well- targeted government subsidies, can play a major role in this strategy.

There is empirical evidence that schooling of the household head, helps explain the source of income, so it should still be considered in these models.

Literatura citada

Ahearn, M. C.; El-Hosta, H. and Dewbre, J. 2006. The impact of coupled a decoupled government subsidies on off-farm labor participation of U.S. farm operators. American Journal of Agricultural Economics. 88(2):393-408. [ Links ]

Avila, D. J.; Puyana, A. y Romero J. 2008. Presente y futuro del sector agrícola mexicano en el contexto del TLCAN. Primera edición. El Colegio de México-UACh. DF, México. 385 p. [ Links ]

Barro, R. J. 1993. Macroeconomía. McGraw Hill Interamericana. DF, México. 562 p. [ Links ]

CONAPO. 2010. Índice de marginación por entidad federativa y municipio 2010. Disponible en: http://www.conapo.gob.mx/work/models/CONAPO/indices_margina/mf2010/ CapitulosPDF/Anexo%20B2.pdf. [ Links ]

Contreras, R. 1993. Perspectivas de la producción de trigo en la región del sur de Sonora frente al Tratado Trilateral de Libre Comercio. CIESTAAM-DCRU-UACh. Chapingo, México. 182 p. [ Links ]

Cortés, F.; Fernández, T. y Minor, M. 2008. Identificación de los mecanismos de aversión de la pobreza en el agro mexicano en el contexto del TLCAN (1992-2002). In: Puyana, A. y Romero, J. (coords). El sector agropecuario y el Tratado de Libre Comercio con America del Norte, efectos socioeconómicos y sociales. Primera edición. El Colegio de México. México. 165 p. [ Links ]

De la Madrid, H. M. 1983. Plan Nacional de Desarrollo. Presidencia de la Republica. Disponible en: http://www.juridicas.unam.mx/publica/librev/rev/rap/cont/55/doc/doc7. [ Links ]

Eliosa, M. J.A. 2012. Migración internacional. Estrategias de sobrevivencia e identidad campesina en San Felipe, Teotlalcingo, Puebla, México. Agricultura, Sociedad y Desarrollo. 9(1):71-84. [ Links ]

Gujarati, N. D. 2009. Econometría. McGraw-Hill Interamericana. México. 598 p. [ Links ]

Guzmán, G. I.; Santiago, C. M. J.; Leos, R. J. A.; González, L. G.; Martínez, D. M. A. y Salas, G. M. 2005. El papel del empleo rural no agrícola en las comunidades rurales: un estudio de caso en Tepeji del Río Hidalgo, México. Agricultura, Sociedad y Desarrollo. 2(2):51-63. [ Links ]

Huffman, W. E. 1980. Farm and off-farm work decisions: the role of human capital. The Review of Economics and Statistic. 62(1):14-23. [ Links ]

INEGI. 2010. Encuesta Nacional de Ingresos y Gastos en los Hogares (ENIGH). Disponible en: Disponible en: http/www.inegi.gob.mx/est/contenidos/español/sistemas/enigh/2010/efault.asp# . Consultado el 24 de agosto de 2013. [ Links ]

López, T. M. G.; Peña, O. B.; Méndez, E. J. A.; Escobedo, G. J. S. y Martínez, S. T. 2011. Migración y remesas: aporte al desarrollo local en regiones de Puebla y Veracruz, México. Agricultura Sociedad y Desarrollo. 8(1):193-208. [ Links ]

Lozano, A. F. 2003. Experiencias internacionales en envío y uso de las remesas. In: Tuirán, R. (coord). Migración México-Estados Unidos. Opciones de política. CONAPO-INEGI. Aguascalientes, México. 1-24 pp. [ Links ]

Mora, R. J. 2004. El impacto de la migración y las remesas en la distribución y fuentes de ingreso: El caso del México rural. In: 1er. Seminario Internacional sobre Migración y Remesas. Instituto de Investigaciones Económicas y Empresariales de la Universidad Michoacana de San Nicolás de Hidalgo. Morelia, Michoacán, México. 1-26 pp. [ Links ]

Nicholson, W. 2005. Microeconomic theory, Basic Principles and Extensions. Novena edition. Thompson South-Western. Canadá. 671 p. [ Links ]

Pat, F. V. G. 2010. Análisis de la competitividad del maíz en la región de los campos menonitas de Hecelchakán, Campeche. Tesis Doctoral. División de Ciencias Económico-Administrativas, Universidad Autónoma Chapingo. Chapingo, México. 106 p. [ Links ]

Puyana, A. y Romero, J. 2009. México de la crisis de la deuda al estancamiento económico. Primera edición. El Colegio de México. DF, México. 391 p. [ Links ]

Román, R. S. I. y Hernández, D. S. 2010. Seguridad alimentaria en el municipio de Oxchuc, Chiapas. Agricultura, Sociedad y Desarrollo. 7(1):71-79. [ Links ]

Salinas de Gortari, C. 1989. Plan Nacional de Desarrollo. Presidencia de la Republica, México. Disponible en: Disponible en: http://www.diputados.gob.mx/cedia/sia/re/RE-ISS-09-06-17 . Consultado el 25 de agosto de 2013. [ Links ]

Taylor, J. E. and Yúnez, N. A. 2000. The returns from schooling in a diversified rural economy. American Journal of Agricultural Economics. 82(2):287-297. [ Links ]

Taylor, J. E.; Yúnez, N. A. and Dyer, G. 1999. Agricultural price policy, employment, and migration in a diversified rural economy: a village- town CGE analysis from Mexico. American Journal of Agricultural Economics. 81(3):653-662. [ Links ]

Yúnez-Naude, A. 2001. Las remesas y el desarrollo rural. In: Seminario Internacional sobre la transferencia y uso de las remesas: Proyectos productivos y de ahorro. CEPAL, Sin Fronteras y Universidad Autónoma de Zacatecas. Zacatecas, México. 1-16 pp. [ Links ]

Received: January 2016; Accepted: May 2016

Creative Commons License Este es un artículo publicado en acceso abierto bajo una licencia Creative Commons