SciELO - Scientific Electronic Library Online

 
vol.17 número3Teorías del crecimiento cara a cara (Englobamiento estadístico: hacia una especificación general)Inclusión financiera de los receptores de remesas en México índice de autoresíndice de materiabúsqueda de artículos
Home Pagelista alfabética de revistas  

Servicios Personalizados

Revista

Articulo

Indicadores

Links relacionados

  • No hay artículos similaresSimilares en SciELO

Compartir


Revista mexicana de economía y finanzas

versión On-line ISSN 2448-6795versión impresa ISSN 1665-5346

Rev. mex. econ. finanz vol.17 no.3 Ciudad de México jul./sep. 2022  Epub 14-Sep-2023

https://doi.org/10.21919/remef.v17i3.653 

Research and review articles

Impact of the Covid19 Pandemic on Remittances to Mexico

Impacto de la pandemia Covid19 en las remesas a México

Alfredo Cuecuecha Mendoza1 

Miguel Cruz Vásquez1  + 

1Universidad Popular Autónoma del Estado de Puebla, México


Abstract

This paper seeks to show the impact of the COVID-19 pandemic on remittances from the United States to Mexico. Using monthly data from January 2014 to May 2021, it shows that there is a structural break in the long and short run equations that explain remittances. Using evidence from orthogonalized impulse response functions, we find that before COVID 19 there was evidence in favor of the altruistic, the risk sharing and the investment motive hypotheses for sending remittances. During the COVID 19 period, there is evidence that remittances became more a necessity reducing space for investment motives and the preferences of the sender households and increasing the role of the risk sharing motive. The main limitation of the study is that we do not show results specific to remittances corridors due to the lack of data. Further research is needed to understand if the COVID 19 has long run impacts over the remittance flow and the usage that receiving households give to the remittances.

Keywords: Covid19; Remittances; Motivations to remit

JEL Classification: J610

Resumen

Este artículo busca mostrar el impacto de la pandemia COVID-19 sobre las remesas enviadas de Estados Unidos a México. Se utilizan datos mensuales desde enero de 2014 y hasta mayo de 2021, para mostrar que existe un cambio estructural en las ecuaciones de corto y largo plazo que explican las remesas. Utilizando información de funciones de impulso respuesta ortogonalizadas, encontramos que antes del COVID 19 existía evidencia a favor de las hipótesis de enviar remesas por razones altruistas, por motivos de inversión y por motivos de administración del riesgo. Durante el COVID 19, hay evidencia de que el envío de remesas se convirtió en una necesidad, reduciéndose el espacio para el envío de remesas por motivos de inversión o el espacio para las preferencias de los hogares que envían remesas, y aumentando el rol de los motivos de administración del riesgo. Los resultados tienen como principal limitante el no mostrar resultados a nivel de corredor de remesas específico, debido a la falta de datos. Mayores estudios son necesarios para comprender si el COVID 19 tiene impactos de más largo plazo sobre los envíos de remesas y los usos que los hogares receptores hacen de las mismas.

Palabras clave: COVID-19; Remesas; Motivos para remitir

Clasificación JEL: J610

1. Introduction

The emergence of the COVID-19 pandemic has brought an increase in the reception of remittances during 2020 for Mexico. In this work we observe that during 2020 Mexico received more than 42,624 million dollars in remittances, coinciding with the arrival of the COVID 19 pandemic, which represents a quarterly average in nominal terms, 652% more than in 1995, 397% more than in 2000, 83% more than in 2010, and 11% more than in 2019, since the remittances of 1995, 2000, 2010 and 2019 amounted to 5,667, 8,572, 23,313 and 38,457 million dollars (Banxico, 2021a).

At the beginning of the arrival of COVID-19, it was considered that the economic contraction generated in the United States through the increase in unemployment in that country, would negatively affect remittances from Mexico, however we observe an aggressive countercyclical policy to reduce unemployment in that country, which has allowed migrants to maintain their income and remittances (Valdivia, Mendoza, Quintana, Salas and Lozano, 2020).

The literature on the motivations to send remittances suggests at least three different approaches to understand why remittances are sent (Elbadawi and Rocha, 1992); the first is grouped within the Endogenous Migration perspective, which considers that the sending of family remittances is an endogenous variable in the migration decision process, along with the length of stay, savings and others; likewise, it values the family relationships and socio-economic aspects of migrants, giving greater weight to the characteristics of migrants and their families, which explains the sending of remittances from an altruistic approach. A second group of explanations, generate results relatively similar to the altruistic approach but are based on risk sharing (Lucas and Stark, 1985). The third group addresses the sending of remittances from the perspective of Portfolio Optimization, in which only the self-interest of migrants motivates the sending of remittances, regardless of their decision to emigrate and the conditions of their family. Macroeconomic-financial variables are more important, especially in terms of investment risk and return considerations (Islas and Moreno, 2011).

To our knowledge, there is no empirical evidence to show the impact of the advent of the COVID-19 pandemic on remittances from the United States to Mexico. This article analyzes the role that the pandemic has had on remittances using a monthly time series from January 2014 through May 2021. The article identifies that the COVID-19 generated a structural break in the reception of remittances, altering both the short and long run relations that remittances held with different variables like the US GDP and Mexico’s GDP. Using Orthogonalized Impulse Response Functions (OIRF’s), our analysis shows that before the COVID 19 pandemic there was evidence in favor of the altruistic, the risk sharing and the self-interested hypothesis to send remittances. The evidence during the COVID 19 pandemic is that remittances became more a necessity reducing the importance of the investment motive and that of pure altruism, leading to an increase in the risk sharing motive.

The rest of the paper is organized as follows. The second section presents a review of some background information on the arrival of the pandemic and the theoretical and empirical literature on the determinants of remittances. The third briefly shows the methodology and presents the variables used in the empirical analysis. The fourth presents the results of the analysis and discusses them with respect to the contributions of previous studies, and the fifth concludes.

2. Theoretical and empirical background

With the arrival of the COVID-19 pandemic, a collapse in remittances from Mexicans was predicted due to the suspension of economic activities in the United States and its impact on unemployment and income of Americans (Valdivia et al., 2020). However, the reality was different, since remittances increased significantly during 2020, because Mexicans have not only managed to keep their jobs, but also the amount of money they sent to their families increased by a percentage close to 11 percent in 2020 compared to 2019 in nominal terms (Banxico, 2020), which contrasts with the decrease in remittances in other labor-exporting countries1.

Among the causes of the increase in remittances from Mexican migrants in the United States despite the emergence of the pandemic, the following are mentioned: i) the 36% depreciation of the Mexican peso against the US dollar during the COVID-19 crisis, since a stronger dollar provides immigrants with additional incentives to send more resources back home, because it can generate more remittances with greater purchasing power in the country of origin (Mandelman and Vilán, 2020), ii) Stimulus programs of economic benefits in the United States, specially the CARES Act (Coronavirus Aid, Relief, and Economic Security Act) that had an amount of more than 2 billion dollars, and which included transfers to 83% of the unemployed Latino population, which allows to ensure that the majority of the Mexican population should have been recipients of the stimulus payment, guaranteeing the sending of remittances even in the COVID-19 pandemic (Domínguez and Miranda, 2021) and iii) the employment of Mexican migrants in activities considered essential to the US economy such as the primary sector, the construction industry, commerce and manufacturing, which were some of the economic activities that were soon opened in that country (Domínguez and Miranda, 2021).

Mandelman and Vilá (2020) also add within the factors that may explain the increase in remittances to Mexico even with the pandemic to the following: 1) industries such as agriculture, including meat and poultry from the United States, are large employers of immigrants and clearly, these are jobs that were not negatively affected by the pandemic and in any case, these industries expanded during the period, 2) although American restaurants stopped receiving customers, there was a considerable increase in “take out” alternatives, so instead of being employed as waiters and waitresses, Mexican immigrants were typically working inside kitchens, and 3) American households that were forced to stay indoors found a particular liking for home improvement and landscaping, sectors that are also disproportionately served by Mexican immigrants.

For their part, Ramírez and Lozano (2021) point out some factors related to the labor participation of Mexican migrants, which put their health at risk but contributed to the increase in remittances, such as the significant number of them who continued to work, despite of being afraid of catching the virus, since most of them are employed in informal and precarious jobs in the United States, so they do not have job benefits and hardly have the opportunity to be absent from work; as well as the fact that they constitute the majority of the workforce employed in the agricultural sector, thus helping to keep supermarkets stocked with fruits and vegetables amid the health crisis caused by COVID-19 that paralyzed several states in the United States, although 45% of them do not have health insurance, as many are hired informally and those who are not unionized lack the necessary information about the dangers of the virus, and similarly, those who work in the field of personal services, especially in the preparation, sale and distribution of food, 47% do not have medical insurance.

On the other hand, in a study on the receiving federative entities of the remittance-sending states during the pandemic, (Banxico, 2020) highlights that despite the emergence of COVID-19 in the United States and the fall of more than 10% of the total employment and employment of Mexican migrants in particular in that country during the period from January to May 2020, there are factors that allowed the increase in remittances in Mexico, such as the higher proportion of documented Mexican immigrants in the United States, and with it, the lower probability of a drop in their remittances to Mexico, which suggests the possibility of a greater receipt of unemployment benefits for this population group. However, it also points out factors that could negatively affect the sending of remittances from the United States to Mexico, such as the degree of affectation caused by the COVID-19 pandemic in the different states of the United States, as well as the contraction of the employment in economic activities that predominantly hire Mexican immigrants, such as construction and lodging and food preparation services.

For its part, the Mexico 2021 Migration and Remittances Yearbook indicates that the COVID-19 crisis negatively impacted the United States labor market and that the unemployment rate of the Mexican migrant population went from 6.6% in March 2020 to 17.1 % in April 2020, but that despite the above, a factor that could increase the reception of remittances in Mexico is the high labor participation of Mexican migrants in essential economic sectors of that country, estimating that almost 20% of the jobs in agriculture, almost 12% of manufacturing jobs, more than 6% of wholesale trade jobs, 4.4% of chemical, plastic and rubber manufacturing jobs, 1.3% of hospital jobs and 2% of work in other health services in the United States was carried out by the Mexican migrant population (BBVA-SGCONAPO, 2021).

Likewise, the previous document adds some factors related to health that seem to explain the resistance of remittances from the United States to Mexico, such as the access of Mexican migrants to health services in that country, since in 2020 only 34% of them did not have coverage of public or private health services, although in contrast, 77.2% of them had some degree of overweight or obesity in the same year and 13.6% had been diagnosed as borderline diabetic or prediabetic between 2017 and 2018; while in 2020, the total Mexican population served by the Ventanillas de Salud program was 3,060,946, and that as of January 4, 2021, 3,384 deaths of Mexicans due to COVID-19 had been registered in the United States (BBVA-SGCONAPO, 2021).

With regard to the theoretical determinants of remittances, because the most common motivation for remittances for migrants is to support the family members who are left behind, wife, children, parents and members of larger family and social circles, the majority of theoretical approaches address remittances as a result of the altruism of migrants, although more recently the migrant's self-interest has been considered as the main reason for sending remittances (Islas and Moreno, 2011; Rapoport and Docquier, 2005).

For example, Rapaport and Docquier (2005) mention that a mixture of individualistic motives of migrants, such as altruism, exchange, strategic motives and inheritances, as well as family agreements, such as insurance, investment and loan repayment, explain the probability and size of remittances2. Other authors such as Andreoni (1989) 3 consider that the factors that determine the sending of remittances constitute impure altruism, while for Lucas and Stark (1985))4 remittances are determined by enlightened selfishness.

In order to carry out empirical analysis on the determinants of the flow of remittances, these in recent times have been classified by Elbadawi and Rocha (1992) in two groups; those that support the idea that family ties affect the flow of remittances and is called the Endogenous Migration perspective, which considers the sending of remittances as an endogenous variable in the migration decision process, in addition to assessing family relationships and socioeconomic aspects of migrants, giving greater weight to the characteristics of migrants and their families, in which altruism is a central resource that directly explains the sending of remittances. Under this approach, the ability to remit is directly linked to the salary received in the host country and the saving behavior of the migrant, among other factors. But most importantly, if altruism is the main reason for sending remittances, remittances would behave more like a normal good, i.e., when income raises remittances would tend to grow.

In one type of model derived from this approach, the migrant is seen as the traditional macroeconomic agent that maximizes intertemporal utility to generate a savings-consumption trajectory both in their place of origin and destination (Djajic, 1989; Djajic and Milbourne, 1988). But in other types of models under this approach, which maintain the endogeneity of the migration decision, but treat remittances as a contractual agreement between the migrant and his family, the terms of which are defined by the bargaining power of the parties, and which it constitutes a risk-sharing arrangement that compensates for the lack of insurance markets in developing countries, particularly in rural areas, by guaranteeing income in difficult times and offering an improved risk-return framework (Lucas and Stark, 1985, Stark and Katz, 1988). The risk sharing argument has important implications, since an increase in income in the receiving country would reduce the need for remittances. Consequently, we decided to split in this paper this first approach into two: one called pure altruism, will reveal itself if remittances are a normal good, and a second one called the risk sharing motive would reveal itself if income at the sending country and income at the receiving country have different effects on remittances.

The second approach in Elbadawi and Rocha (1992), which for us constitutes a third explanation for remittances, is called Portfolio Optimization and considers that remittances are only a transfer of savings from one place to another, in which only the self-interest of migrants motivates the sending of money, regardless of the idea of ​​migrating and of the conditions of their family, and that the migrants decide where to house their savings and maximize their utility by determining their personal consumption and the amount allocated to financial instruments both in the country of origin and in the host country, the macroeconomic-financial variables being more relevant as the decision to remit is dependent on risk and return on investment (Islas and Moreno, 2011).

Models derived from this approach focus on relative rates of return, relative prices, and uncertainty as basic determinants in the decision to remit (Swamy, 1981; Miranda, 1988).

Following what was proposed by Elbadawi and Rocha (1992), Islas and Moreno (2011) made a synthesis of the Endogenous Migration and Portfolio Optimization perspectives, forming two components of remittances: (i) required and (ii) desired (or voluntary), establishing that the Endogenous Migration perspective explains the existence and behavior of the first component and takes into account the situation of the migrant's family, through variables such as differences in income, savings and expectations between the countries of origin and host, the stock of migrants, the length of stay, while the Portfolio Optimization perspective explains the second component and takes into account mainly financial variables, such as the interest rate differential between the home and host countries, the domestic inflation rate, and the exchange rate differential.

On the other hand, in order to determine whether the macroeconomic conditions of the migrant's countries of origin and host should be included within the determinants of remittances, Vargas-Silva and Huang (2005) developed an intertemporal model that explicitly expresses the relationship between the flow of family remittances and the macroeconomic conditions of both countries, assuming that remittances are sent in the first period and that the migrant returns to their country of origin in the second period. They assume that the utility of the migrant in the first period depends on his consumption in the host country and the consumption of his family in the country of origin, which in turn depends on the economic conditions of the country of origin, while the income of the migrant it depends on the economic conditions of the host country, concluding that the improvement of the economic conditions of the host country causes an increase in remittances; that is, the migrant sends more remittances because their economic condition improves, and that in the same way, if the migrant is sending money for altruistic reasons and the conditions of the country of origin improve, then they send less money because their family is in better conditions without remittances. Likewise, by increasing the return on savings in the host country, the migrant could increase their savings and thereby decrease their remittances, or they could decrease their savings since the increased return would allow them to save less and thereby increase their remittances, concluding that the empirical analysis of remittances should include the macroeconomic variables of the migrant's country of origin, as well as those of the host country.

Regarding the results of empirical studies on the subject carried out under the Endogenous Migration and Portfolio Optimization approaches, Islas and Moreno (2011) point out that the results reported by the literature are not robust, mainly due to differences in the preferences of migrants, relationships between macroeconomic variables and remittances that vary according to the importance of the altruistic effect and implicit contracts, presence of non-robust signs in the indicators of income, inflation, interest rates and exchange rates of the place of origin, possible endogeneity of economic growth that could affect the results of the relationship between remittances and indicators of domestic production, as well such as the use of samples from different countries, regions and temporalities, among other causes, which is addressed in our article by estimating the impact of the COVID 19 pandemic on remittances as well as the interactions between the COVID 19 pandemic and some control variables on remittances

The inconsistency of the results of the empirical studies on the subject is shown when we observe the determinants of the type of endogenous migration of remittances that Swamy (1981), Solimano (2001), Giuliano and Ruiz Arrauz (2005) and Islas and Moreno (2011) find that remittances are positively related to economic conditions and the GDP of the remittance-receiving country, while El-Sakka and Mcnabb (1999), Castillo (2001), Faini (1994) and Islas and Moreno (2011), Aydas, Neyapti and Ozca (2005) and Gupta (2005), find that remittances are negatively related to economic activity and wages in the remittance-receiving country. On the other hand, Elbadawi and Rocha (1992), Castillo (2001), Aydas, Neyapti and Ozca (2005), Gupta (2005), Vargas Silva and Huang and (2006), Mouhoub, Oudinet and Ozca (2008) and Swamy (1981) find a positive relationship between the economic situation of the host country and remittances.

Such inconsistency is also observed in the determinants of the type of portfolio optimization, Faini (1994) finds that the real exchange rate is positively related to remittances, while El-Sakka, and Mcnabb (1999), Castillo (2001) find that remittances are negatively related to the real exchange rate. On the other hand, Islas and Moreno (2011) and El-Sakka and McNabb (1999) find a negative and statistically significant relationship between remittances and the interest rate differential, while Aydas, Neyapti and Ozca (2005) find a positive relationship between the interest rate differential and remittances.

3. Methodology

We start by proposing a linear model between remittances (Rt) and migration and portfolio factors, which is closely related to the models proposed by Islas and Moreno (2011), Vargas-Silva & Huang (2005) and Elbadawi and Rocha (1992). Due to data limitations, we implement a simplified version as follows:

Rt=β0+β1GDPMX,t+β2GDPUS,t+β3WageMt+β4WageUt+β5IRDt+β6ERt+εt (1)

Where the factors related to the endogenous migration perspective are GDPMX,t, which is the Gross Domestic Product in Mexico in period t; GDPUS,t is the Gross Domestic Product of the United States in period t; WageMt is the real Mexico wage; WageU is the real US age. The factors related to portfolio optimization are IRDt which is the interest rate differential between México and the US, measured by the monthly average interbank interest rate in Mexico and the average monthly federal funds rate in the United States; and ERt which is the nominal exchange rate in Mexico in period t.

The sign of the parameter β1 can be negative if, on average, individuals send less remittances to Mexico when growth in Mexico is observed, which would be consistent with the risk sharing hypothesis. On the other hand, it can be positive if individuals invest in Mexico when the country is growing, which would be consistent with the portfolio hypothesis. Notice that, in principle, there is no implication for the altruistic model, if the increase of need does not change the willingness to contribute. But if the increase in need raises the willingness to contribute, then a negative relation would also be consistent with the altruistic hypothesis.

The sign for β2 is expected to be positive since growth in the US would generate higher income in the US, which increases the number of remittances either because individuals have more income that they can invest or if individuals are more affluent and can become more altruistic.

In the case of the sign for β3 the sign could be negative if a higher real Mexico wage generates that the migrant individuals will send less remittances. It could be positive if individuals are investing in Mexico.

The expected sign for β4 is positive if an increase in the US wage increases the number of individuals migrating to the US and sending remittances.

In the case of β5, an increase in the Mexico-US interest rate differential generates more investment in México.

In the case of β6 it could be positive if a depreciation of the peso generates a higher purchasing power of dollars in Mexico and consequently more investment in real assets.

To study the time-break that COVID-19 imposes in the equation, we start by looking at a potential shift in the constant of the linear model, which is obtained using a dummy variable that takes the value of 1 for all months of 2020 after February, as well as for the first five months of 2021, and takes the value of zero in every other month.

Rt=β0+β1GDPMX,t+β2GDPUS,t+β3WageMt+β4WageUt+β5IRDt+β6ERt+β7Covidt+εt (2)

Equation (2) however, can be estimated with bias in the presence of cointegration, which would occur if the variables are I(1) and if at least one linear combination of them is I(0) (Engle & Granger, 1987; Castillo, 2001). We apply the augmented test of Dickey-Fuller to test for the existence of unit roots in each of the series analyzed.5

Moreover, if the series are I(1) the existence of time-breaks could be confused with the existence of a unit root, which would require a test for time breaks that would take into account the potential existence of unit roots (Phillips and Perron, 1988; Mendoza-González & Villagra-Piña, 2021). Because of this, we apply the test of Clemente, Montañes and Reyes (1998) which test for the existence of time breaks in the presence of unit roots and structural breaks. Likewise, we apply the test of Wagner and Weid (2017) that allows to monitor for changes in the cointegration relationships.

Given the results for the existence of I(1) series and at least one potential cointegration relationship, we apply the Vector Error Correction (VEC) methodology to estimate the relationship between the variables proposed including the estimation of the cointegration equations. The Vec estimated is given by:

Yt=αβ'Yt-1+i=14ΓiΔYt-i+v+εt (3)

Where Yt=Rt,GDPMX,t,GDPUS,t,WageMt,WageUt, IRDt,ERt, and the number of lags as well as whether or not a trend was needed was determined using the Akaike Information Criterion (AIC) and the Schwarz-Bayesian Information Criterion (SBIC). The number of cointegrating equation is also determined using the Trace statistic proposed by Johansen (1991).

We also estimated the Orthogonalized Impulse Response Function (OIRF) for the period excluding the COVID 19 months and for the period including the COVID 19 months. We could not estimate the VEC for only the months where COVID 19 took place because of insufficient data points, consequently we settled for showing what the inclusion of the COVID 19 months generates on the estimated IRF’s.6

4. Data

The series used are monthly and use information from 2014 and onward up to May 2021 the last month with complete information for all variables. We have information before 2014 for the different variables, however, exploratory analysis showed us that a structural change took place after 2009 and for the series of remittances a break was also detected in mid 2013. Consequently, we chose to focus after December 2013.

The monthly data for Remittances is presented in millions of dollars and comes from Banxico (2021a); the data for Mexico’s GDP is proxied using the Economic Activity General Index (IGAE, for its acronym in Spanish) and comes from INEGI (2021a); the data for the GDP of the US is proxied by an index provided by the Federal Reserve Economic Data (FRED) from the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Bank (FRED, 2021). The data for Mexico’s wages is the monthly index for real minimum wages that comes from Banco de Mexico (Banxico, 2021b), while the data for the wages of the US are the average hourly wage earnings that are provided by the Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS, 2021a). The average monthly Federal Funds rate comes from Banco de México (Banxico, 2021c), while Mexico’s 28 days average interbank interest rate comes from Banco de México (Banxico, 2021d). The nominal exchange rate comes from Banco de México (Banxico, 2021e), while the consumer prices index for Mexico is obtained from INEGI (2021b) and the consumer price index for the US comes from the Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS, 2021b). The transformations to real figures were carried out based on the prices for January 2019 for both Mexico and the United States.

Graph 1 shows the evolution of remittances in real terms for the period 1995-2021, transformed from monthly to quarterly data. Between 1995 and 2021, the trend in the flow of remittances, in real terms, has been positive. It had a period of stability in the 1990s, while at the beginning of the new century it increased considerably, although a significant increase in volatility is also observed. The continuous growth of remittances during the period under study has been exposed in works such as that of (Islas and Moreno, 2011), which indicates an average of 3,000 million dollars in the early nineties, an average of about 6,000 million dollars in 1998, and the overcoming of the 10,000 million dollars barrier in the first semester of 2006. In our work we observe that during 2020 Mexico received more than 40,000 million dollars, coinciding with the arrival of the COVID pandemic19, which represents a quarterly average in real terms, 600% more than in 1995, 300% more than in 2000, 61% more than in 2010, and 10% more than in 2019.

Source: Banxico (2021a).

Graph 1 Quarterly Flow of remittances from the United States to Mexico. 

The above behavior indicates the need to differentiate the data because it is clearly non-stationary. Formal tests are carried out in the next section that will show that the monthly data becomes stationary using the first difference, and /or the first difference of the 12th seasonal difference.

Table 1 briefly describes the mean values of the series included in the model, each variable measured in its first monthly log difference, which approximates month to month percent changes. Table 1 clearly shows how dramatic the Covid 19 period was for remittances since it presents a growth of about 2% per month, when for the 2014-2019 period the growth was approximately .6%. For the entire period studied, remittances grew at .8%. These results are preliminary since different econometric challenges need to be corrected before a final verdict can be expressed.

Table 1 Mean Values for Selected Variables 

All 2014-2019 2020-2021
D.Remittances Mean 0.008 0.006 0.019
S.E. 0.116 0.104 0.162
N 89 72 17
D.US GDP Mean 0.004 0.01 -0.022
S.E. 0.188 0.19 0.181
N 89 72 17
D.MX GDP Mean -0.002 -0.002 -0.004
S.E. 0.04 0.032 0.066
N 89 72 17
Exchange rate Mean 0.005 0.005 0.003
S.E. 0.033 0.027 0.053
N 89 72 17
lnterest Rate Differential Mean 0.002 0.007 -0.022
S.E. 0.035 0.03 0.044
N 89 72 17
US Wage Mean 0.001 0.001 0.001
S.E. 0.007 0.003 0.015
N 89 72 17
MX Wage Mean 0.006 0.003 0.015
S.E. 0.032 0.024 0.053
N 89 72 17

Source: Own calculations based on data from INEGI (2021a, 2021b), FRED (2021), BLS (2021a, 2021b), Banxico (2021a, 2021b, 2021c, 2021d, 2021e)

Table 1 also shows that the GDP of US increased .01% per month in the 2014-2019 period, while it declined .02% during the 2020-2021 period. In the case of Mexico, the GDP contracted -.2% previous to the Covid 19 period and it contracted -.4% during the Covid 19 period. The exchange rate depreciated .5% during the pre Covid 19 period and depreciated .3% during the Covid 19 period. The interest rate differential grew .7% previous to the Covid 19 period and contracted -2.2% during the Covid 19 period. The US wage grew in real terms .1% both before and after the Covid 19 period. Mexico’s real wage grew .3% previous to the COVID 19 period and grew 1.5% during the Covid 19 period.

5. Results for the Linear Model

The results for the linear estimations are shown in Table 2. The R squared of the equation shows that our simple linear model can explain 81% of the variation observed in remittances for the first differenced data, while it explains 53% of the variation for the first difference of the seasonally differenced data.

Table 2 Linear Models for Remittances 

  First Difference FD of Seasonally
differenced
US GDP 0.04 0.02
-0.03 -0.02
MX GDP 0.98*** 1.08***
-0.2 -0.19
Nominal Exchange Rate 1.10*** 1.17***
-0.16 -0.13
Interest Rate Differential -0.1 -0.08
-0.08 -0.07
US wage -4.14** -4.09***
-1.24 -0.96
MX wage 0.17 0.51
-0.23 -0.26
Covid 19 0.03 0.01
  -0.02 -0.02
Constant -0.07*** 0.02
  -0.01 -0.02
R_squared 0.81 0.53
N 182 181

***Significant at 1%, **Significant at 5%

A 1% increase in Mexico’s GDP increases remittances between .98% and 1.08%, which agrees with the investment hypothesis. Comparing the results found in this paper with those found in other empirical studies, we find that they agree with those of Swamy (1981), Solimano (2001), and Giuliano and Ruiz Arrauz (2005), all of which found a positive relation between remittances and the GDP of the remittance-receiving country. They contrast with those of El-Sakka and Mcnabb (1999), Castillo (2001), Faini (1994), Islas and Moreno (2011), Aydas et al (2005) and Gupta (2005), which find a negative relationship between GDP and remittances.

A 1% increase in US’ GDP increases remittances between .02% and .04%, but it is not statistically significant. The positive sign coincides with the results of Elbadawi and Rocha (1992), Castillo (2001), Aydas et al (2005), Gupta (2005), Vargas Silva y Huang (2006), Mouhoub et al (2008) and Swamy (1981).

A one percent increase in the Nominal Exchange Rate increases remittances between 1.1.% and 1.17% percent. This result indicates that the portfolio motive to send remittances is also present. Our results also agree in sign with those of Faini (1994). However, they do not agree with El-Sakka and Mcnabb (1999), and Castillo (2001), because those authors found a negative relation between remittances and the real exchange rate.

The Interest rate differential is not statistically significant. This result does not agree with those of Islas and Moreno (2011), and El-Sakka and Mcnabb (1999), since they find a negative and statistically significant relationship between remittances and the interest rate differential. Our results also do not agree with those of Aydas et al (2005), that find a positive relationship between the differential of interest rates and remittances.

A 1% increase in the US wage reduces between 4.09% and 4.14% remittances. Since an increase in the US wage, keeping other things equal, increases the US-Mexico wage differential and this is linked positively to migration (Cuecuecha, Fuentes-Mayorga & McLeod, 2021), an increase in the US wage reduces remittances, perhaps because new migrants need to pay their migratory costs when they have recently arrived at the US.

An increase in the Mexican real wage does not changes remittances. The sign obtained is positive which is consistent with the idea that individuals are investing in Mexico.

Table 2 also shows that the coefficient for COVID 19 is not statistically significant. This result needs to be taken with caution for the reasons given before. We now proceed to test for the existence of stationarity and cointegration in the data.

6. Results of Unit Root and Cointegration tests

As explained before, Model (2) may be biased if there exists at least one cointegration relation between the variables in vector Yt. Table 3 shows the results from Augmented Dickey Fuller tests that demonstrate that all the elements of vector Yt are I(1) processes, since they have a unit root in log-level units and are stationary in their first difference log-level units. Similarly, the third column of Table 3 presents results for the variables expressed as the first difference of the seasonally differenced data of the log units, showing that all variables are stationary.

Table 3 Results for Augmented Dickey Fuller Tests, all variables in log units 

Level 1st Difference 12-month
seasonal
difference &
1st Difference
Remittances -1.7 -8.33 -11.55
[0.43] [0.0] [0.0]
US GDP -2.72 -10.43 -10.4
[.07] [0.0] [0.0]
MX GDP -1.56 -10.55 -5.11
[.50] [0.0] [0.0]
Nominal Exchange Rate -0.96 -7.93 -7.1
[.76] [0.0] [0.0]
Interest Rate Differential -2.76 -4.63 -4.04
[.06] [0.0] [0.0]
US wage -0.77 -8.15 -7.2
[.82] [0.0] [0.0]
MX wage 1.64 -8.86 -10.1
[.99] [0.0] [0.0]
N 182 181 169

P-values in brackets

Table 4 presents tests that allow to determine the existence of cointegration relations among the variables that form vector Yt. All variables are measured in log units. The Johansen (1991) test for Cointegration confirms that at least two cointegration equation exists in the mentioned vector. The number of lags and the selection of a constant trend was done following the AIC and SBIC, as mentioned before.7 Table 4b shows similar results for the data using the 12th seasonal difference on the log units.

Table 4a Johansen tests for cointegration for first difference of log unit 

Trend: constant Number of obs = 89
Sample: 2014m1 - 2021m5 Lags = 4
Max. Rank Parms. LL Eigenvalue Trace
statistic
5% critical
value
0 154 1368.2834 . 176.4608 124.24
1 167 1402.5976 0.5375 107.8324 94.15
2 178 1424.4635 0.38821 64.1007* 68.52
3 187 1439.0543 0.27955 34.9191 47.21
4 194 1447.4397 0.17175 18.1482 29.68
5 199 1452.7231 0.11195 7.5815 15.41
6 202 1456.5133 0.08165 0.001 3.76
7 203 1456.5138 0.00001

*Cut off point.

Table 4b Johansen Test of Cointegration for first difference of seasonally differenced log unit data 

Trend: constant Number of obs = 89
Sample: 2014m1-2021m5 Lags = 4
Max rank Parms LL Eigenvalue Trace
statistics
5% critical
value
0 154 1343.88 . 180.11 146.76
1 168 1373.04 0.481 121.78 114.9
2 180 1395.62 0.398 76.64* 87.31
3 190 1408.56 0.252 50.74 62.99
4 198 1419.02 0.209 29.83 42.44
5 204 1426.04 0.146 15.8 25.32
6 208 1431.02 0.106 5.82 12.25
7 210 1433.94 0.063

*Cut off point.

7. Results for tests of structural break

The procedure of Clemente, Montañes and Reyes (CMR) (1998) tests whether there is a unit root under an unknown structural break, that is identified optimally. The structural break is modelled either as an additive outlier or as an innovational outlier, while one and up to two optimal breaks may be allowed in estimation. The test was performed over the data in first difference of log units. Table 5 shows that the CMR test detects structural breaks for periods post Covid 19 in two out of four tests, however, the structural breaks are not statistically significant at the 5% level. In the case of the data in the first difference of the seasonally difference of log units, the CMR test detects structural breaks in two out of four tests, this time the breaks are significant at the 10% level.

Table 5 Tests for structural break, all data in log units 

Test Data set T-Stat Optimal
breaks
Additive
Outlier
Innovational
Outlier
Clemente-Montañes-Reyes (1998) First difference -0.17 2018m1,
2018m5
No Yes
FD of Seasonal 12th difference 2.27** 2020m2,
2020m6
No Yes
Clemente-Montañes-Reyes (1998) First difference 1.35 2018m4 No Yes
FD of Seasonal 12th difference 1.83* 2020m2 No Yes
Clemente-Montañes-Reyes (1998) First difference 1.28 2019m1,
2020m1
Yes No
FD of Seasonal 12th difference 0.51 2016m9,
2020m1
Yes No
Clemente-Montañes-Reyes (1998) First difference 0.55 2020m12 Yes No
FD of Seasonal 12th difference 0.47 2020m1 Yes No
Hms
Wagner-Wied (2017) First difference 0.3945a 2020m4 NA NA
FD of Seasonal 12th difference 0.2379a 2020m4 NA NA

*10 % significance, **5% significance, a Greater than an estimated value of .22 for the Hms statistic obtained from Table I from Wagner & Wied (2017)

The test of Wagner and Wied (2017) monitor the cointegration relation that exists during a period where structural breaks are suspected to have occurred. The test is performed also over the data in first difference and for the first difference of the seasonal difference of log units. The tests attempt to monitor if a change in the cointegration relation is detected, once the sum of the squared of the estimated residuals diverge above the long run variance, which is estimated for a period where no structural break is assumed to occur. We use as the comparison point the period between 2014 and below 2020. Exploratory analysis detected potential structural breaks during 2013 and we decided to focus attention in the post 2013 period. The Wagner-Wied test shows that the structural break took place in 2020m4. These results add to the evidence obtained from the CMR tests that a structural break took place during the Covid 19 period.

8. Results for estimated VEC models

Given the above results, we proceed to estimate two different VEC systems, one for the pre-COVID 19 period and a second one including the COVID 19 period. Ideally, a different VEC could have been estimated for the Covid 19 period, however, there are not enough observations at this moment to attempt such estimation. All variables are used as the first difference or as the first difference of seasonally differenced data in log units.

Table 6 shows the coefficients for the different VEC estimations for the remittances equation. Four estimations are performed, for the first difference data and Pre Covid 19 period, the FD of the seasonally differenced data and Pre Covid 19 period, the first difference data including the Covid 19 period, and the FD of the seasonally differenced data including the Covid 19 period.8

Table 6 Coefficients for the Remittances equation in VEC estimations, log units data 

Pre Covid 19 Including Covid 19
First
Difference
12th Seasonal
Difference
First
Difference
12th Seasonal
Difference
Coint. Eq. 1 -1.24*** -2.02*** -1.43*** -1.08***
-0.37 -0.52 -0.27 -0.23
Coint. Eq. 2 0.32** -0.07 0.19** -0.06***
-0.12 -0.06 -0.06 -0.02
LD.Remittances -0.28 0.85* -0.05 0.59*
-0.35 -0.42 -0.23 -0.28
L2D.Remittances -0.35 0.34 -0.13 0.36
-0.28 -0.32 -0.19 -0.27
L3D.Remittances -0.02 -0.02 0.08 0.19
-0.17 -0.21 -0.12 -0.18
LD.USGDP -0.24* 0.11 -0.18** 0.08
-0.11 -0.06 -0.07 -0.04
L2D.USGDP -0.11 0.06 -0.11 0.08*
-0.08 -0.06 -0.06 -0.04
L3D.USGDP 0.02 0.01 0.01 0.06
-0.05 -0.05 -0.04 -0.04
LD.MXGDP 3.01* 5.40*** 3.91*** -0.87*
-1.32 -1.55 -0.87 -0.44
L2D.MXGDP 2.46** 4.11** 2.97*** 0.1
-0.95 -1.38 -0.7 -0.45
L3D.MXGDP 0.54 1.57 0.58 -0.08
-0.59 -0.89 -0.47 -0.39
LD.NominalER 0.35 -1.26* 0.66 -1.24***
-0.51 -0.54 -0.38 -0.34
L2D.NominalER 0.19 0.26 0.74 0.47
-0.42 -0.41 -0.38 -0.36
L3D.NominalER -0.38 -0.04 0.24 -0.31
-0.45 -0.42 -0.37 -0.35
LD.InterestRD -0.07 -0.28 0.3 -0.19
-0.36 -0.25 -0.29 -0.19
L2D.InterestRD -0.32 0.03 0.11 0.05
-0.4 -0.26 -0.34 -0.21
L3D.InterestRD -0.38 -0.17 -0.08 -0.11
-0.35 -0.27 -0.29 -0.21
LD.USWage 0.76 3.09 13.63*** -2.18
-4.11 -3 -3.07 -1.78
L2D.USWage -1.99 3.21 10.20*** -0.63
-4.22 -3.25 -2.65 -1.99
L3D.USWage -6.71 5.58 3.52 0.48
-3.74 -3.37 -1.92 -1.91
LD.MXWage 0.49 -0.16 0.17 -0.2
-0.51 -0.43 -0.3 -0.41
L2D.MXWage 0.43 -0.15 0.86* -0.1
-0.52 -0.44 -0.36 -0.4
L3D.MXWage 0.11 -0.1 0.4 -0.48
-0.39 -0.39 -0.31 -0.35
R2 88% 62% 90% 66%
N 72 72 89 89
AIC -29.33 -30.78 -26.44 -27.19
SBIC -23.7 -20.15 -21.4 -22.21

*Significant at 10%, **Significant at 5%, *** Significant at 1%.

Table 6 presents the results for the remittances equation from the four estimated VECs. The first column shows that the two cointegration equations are statistically significant. Also, the first column presents the short run parameters where it is found a negative relation between the US GDP and remittances, which contrasts with our previous result in the linear model where no relation was found. The short run parameters for Mexico’s GDP are positive and significant, which confirms our previous result in the linear model. The nominal exchange rate is found to be non-statistically significant which also contrasts with the linear model where a positive relation was found. We also find that the coefficients for the US wage are not statistically significant which contrasts with our linear model where a negative relationship was found. So basically, this negative relationship was substituted by the negative relationship found between remittances and the US GDP.

The second column presents the results for the first difference of the seasonally differenced data. Only the first cointegration equation is statistically significant. Past values of remittances are statistically significant and positive, which is indicative of dynamic effects perhaps due to social networks effects or due to reductions in costs of remittance reception. The US GDP is not statistically significant. The Mexican GDP is statistically significant again. The nominal exchange rate is found negative and statistically significant, which coincides with the linear OLS model. No other variable is found statistically significant. It is important to notice that the AIC and SBIC show smaller numbers for this 12th differenced data model, so it implies that the seasonally differenced data is better represented by the model, than the first differenced data.

The third column shows the results for the first differenced data including the Covid 19 period. The two cointegration equations continue to be statistically significant. The US GDP and the Mexico GDP continue to be statistically significant. However, now the US wage and the Mexico wage become positive and statistically significant. These results show changes in the short run parameters of the remittances equation.

The fourth column shows the results for the first difference of the seasonally differenced data. The two cointegration equations are now statistically significant, which contrasts with what was found in the Pre Covid data. The US GDP is found positive and statistically significant, which contrast with the results Pre Covid, when no relation was found. The Mexico GDP is found negative and statistically significant, which contrast with the pre Covid data, where it was found positive. The nominal exchange rate is found negative and significant, which coincides with the pre Covid data. No other coefficient is found statistically significant which contrasts with the pre Covid data where the US and Mexico wage were found significant. The AIC and the SBIC show smaller numbers for this model, versus the first differenced data. These results imply that our preferred results are those obtained with the seasonally differenced data.

Table 7 presents the results for the long run coefficients for the two cointegration equations, only for the FD of the seasonally differenced data for the Pre Covid period and the data including the Covid period. The coefficient for the Mexican GDP goes from positive to negative in the first cointegration equation between the Pre Covid and the data including the Covid period. The coefficient for the nominal exchange rate goes from non-significant to positive in the second cointegration equation, between the pre Covid and the data including the Covid period. The coefficient for the interest rate now goes from negative to non-significant in the first cointegration equation between the Pre Covid and the data including the Covid period. The coefficient for the Mexico wage goes from non-significant to negative and significant in the first cointegration equation. These results demonstrate that there were changes both in the short run parameters and the long run parameters.

Table 7 Cointegration Equations, First difference of the seasonally differenced data in log units 

Pre Covid 19 Including Covid 19
Eq. 1 Eq. 2 Eq. 1 Eq. 2
D.MXGDP 3.13*** 0.29 -0.72** -0.35
[0.49] [4.75] [0.32] [4.68]
D.NominalER -0.74*** 0.53 -0.32** 10.85***
[0.12] [1.11] [0.15] [2.26]
D.InterestRD -0.03** -0.32** -0.01 -1.35***
[0.01] [0.13] [0.04] [0.53]
D.USWage 1.67*** -11.98** 2.93* -104.33***
[0.56] [5.38] [1.62] [23.74]
D.MXWage -0.02 -3.37*** -0.86*** 9.44***
[0.09] [0.86] [0.23] [3.37]
X2 117.5*** 75.4*** 117.5*** 75.4***

We now show the Orthogonalized Impulse Response Functions (OIRF) for the equation of the remittances. We want to explore what are the implications of the Covid 19 period for predicted innovations in the different variables of the model, so we will present the OIRF for pre Covid period and the data including the Covid period.

Graph 2 shows the OIRF for the expected response in the reception of remittances to one innovation occurring in US GDP. The Graph clearly shows that in the Pre-Covid 19 period remittances were a normal good, while they become an inferior good during the pandemic. This probably shows that providing remittances during the pandemic became a necessity and it was no longer a luxury good that senders could afford.

Graph 2 Response of Remittances to Changes in USGDP 

Graph 3 shows that the relation between remittances and Mexico’s GDP changed due to the pandemic. Before the pandemic, a positive innovation in Mexico’s GDP would increase remittances, showing the investment motive. Post pandemic, a positive innovation in Mexico’s GDP would reduce remittances, showing the logic of the risk sharing argument.

Graph 3 Response of Remittances to Changes in MX GDP 

Graph 4 shows that the response to one innovation in the exchange rate went from positive to negative. When the sign was positive, this showed the logic of the investment argument, while when a negative sign is observed the logic of the risk sharing argument, i.e. when the purchasing power of remittances in pesos raises there is less need to send remittances. Notice that the altruistic hypothesis would probably imply also a positive sign of the exchange rate.

Graph 4 Response of Remittances to Changes in Exchange Rate 

Graph 5 presents the response to one innovation in the interest rate differential. The sign goes from positive to negative. Notice that the positive sign is consistent with the portfolio motive, while a negative sign is consistent with a risk sharing argument, complemented with incentives: if household members in Mexico save, an increase in the interest rate would increase the return to the their savings and they will require less remittances, but if the household members in Mexico are indebted, then a reduction in remittances would punish household members for the contracted debts.

Graph 5 Response of Remittances to Interest Rate Diff. 

Graph 6 shows the response to innovations in the US wage. While the sign remains negative, it becomes smaller in the Covid 19 period. This result may indicate two things: first, that altruistic consumption is not proportional to the wage per hour and perhaps it is a fixed amount and consequently declining on the wage per hour; second, it may indicate that during the Covid 19 period sending remittances becomes a necessity depending less on the preferences of the sender, and consequently becomes a response converging towards a negative number, which is consistent with what was found in the relation between the US GDP and remittances.

Graph 6 Response of Remittances to US wage 

Graph 7 presents how remittances respond to innovations in Mexico’s wage. It is negative and bigger during the period previous to the Covid 19. The sign is consistent with the idea of the risk sharing argument. The reduction in the sign, probably shows that the behavior of wages in Mexico became less important, probably because less households that receive remittances have less members working in Mexico.

Graph 7 Response of Remittances to MX wage 

In general, the results manifest the reduction of the investment motive, as well as the reduction in the altruistic motive and a raising importance of the risk sharing argument, since, in general, coefficients tended to show responses that would show reductions in remittances when there is less need for them and increases in remittances when there is more economic need for them.

9. Conclusions, recommendations, and final considerations

With the arrival of the COVID-19 pandemic, a collapse in remittances from Mexicans was predicted due to the suspension of economic activities in the United States and its impact on unemployment and income of Americans; however, the reality was different, since remittances increased significantly during 2020, because Mexicans have not only managed to keep their jobs, but also the amount of money they sent to their families increased.

This paper seeks to show the impact of the Covid19 pandemic on remittances from the United States to Mexico. Our results provide evidence that the COVID-19 pandemic changed the long run and the short run relations that remittances held with the different variables that explained them. Before the Covid 19 pandemic, there is evidence in favor of the altruistic motivation to send remittances, as well as for the investment and risk sharing motives. During the Covid 19 pandemic, there is evidence that remittances have become more a necessity relying less on the preferences of individuals and reducing the investment motivations. Consequently, there is evidence in favor that the risk sharing argument is dominating the dynamics of the flow of remittances.

A first limitation of our results is that they do not show what occurs for each remittance corridor that exists between Mexico and the United States, since they may present heterogeneous behaviors. However, while the data for Mexico is disaggregated by Mexican state, the reception of remittances is aggregated from all origins, which does not allow to separate out between remittance corridors. This heterogeneity may be important because of the differences in occupations, migratory status, and time of residence that Mexicans may have, which most likely varies according to the US region where they reside.

A second limitation of this study is that it does not control for the number of Mexicans that reside in the US. This was done mainly because of lack of data since a reliable source for monthly information on the Mexicans that reside in the US does not exist. Our only options for annual data are the March Current Population Survey, which realizes an oversample of the US population and can find Mexican immigrants, and the American Community Survey, which also provides an annual estimation of the Mexico born population residing in the US. An option could be the use of interpolated data using both the monthly CPS and the American Community Survey, however, we considered that a monthly estimation of the Mexico born population residing in the US was outside the scope of this paper.

These results also manifest the need for further research to better understand why there is evidence of lower incentives for sending remittances for investment and altruistic reasons, also to understand the effects that the increase for remittances due to risk sharing reasons could generate, including if such changes may be explained by changes in the characteristics of the individuals that send remittances, or for changes in the characteristics of the individuals that receive remittances. Similarly, whether these changes in the motivations to send remittances may affect the usage of remittances, as well as the consequences for income distribution within the household, between households, within and between regions.

Further analyses are also needed to fully comprehend the scale of the pandemic and its effects on migration, household’s expenditures and household’s portfolio choices.

References

Andreoni, J. (1989). Giving with impure altruism: Applications to charity and Ricardian equivalence, Journal of Political Economy, 97-6: 1447-58. https://doi.org/10.1086/261662 [ Links ]

Aydas, O., B. Neyapti & K. Metin-Ozcan (2005). “Determinants of Workers Remittances: The case of Turkey”, Emerging Markets Finance and Trade, Vol. 41(3). https://doi.org/10.1080/1540496x.2005.11052609 [ Links ]

Banxico (2021a). Ingresos por Remesas. Sistema de Información Económica. Banco de México. Disponible en: https://www.banxico.org.mx/SieInternet/consultarDirectorioInternetAction.do?accion=consultarCuadro&idCuadro=CE81&locale=esLinks ]

Banxico (2021b). Salarios Mínimos General, Índice Real. Sistema de Información Económica. Banco de México. Disponible en: https://www.banxico.org.mx/SieInternet/consultarDirectorioInternetAction.do?sector=10&accion=consultarCuadroAnalitico&idCuadro=CA601&locale=eshLinks ]

Banxico (2021c). Tasa de Fondos Federales Anualizada. Tasas de Interés en los Mercados Internacionales. Sistema de Información Económica. Banco de México. Disponible en: https://www.banxico.org.mx/SieInternet/consultarDirectorioInternetAction.do?sector=18&accion=consultarCuadro&idCuadro=CI34&locale=esLinks ]

Banxico (2021d). Tasas de Interés Interbancarias, Fondeo y Pagaré Bancario Bursátil. Sistema de Información Económica. Banco de México. Disponible en: https://www.banxico.org.mx/SieInternet/consultarDirectorioInternetAction.do?sector=18&accion=consultarCuadro&idCuadro=CF113&locale=esLinks ]

Banxico (2021e). Tipo de cambio promedio del periodo. Sistema de Información Económica. Banco de México. Disponible en: https://www.banxico.org.mx/SieInternet/consultarDirectorioInternetAction.do?sector=6&accion=consultarCuadro&idCuadro=CF86&locale=esLinks ]

Banxico (2020). Remesas en las Entidades Federativas de México en el Contexto de la Pandemia de COVID-19. Extracto del Reporte sobre las Economías Regionales Abril-Junio 2020, Recuadro 2, pp. 20-26. [ Links ]

BLS (2021a). Average hourly earnings of all. Employment, Hours and Earnings from the Current Employment Statistics Survey. Bureau of Labor Statistics. Available at: https://www.bls.gov/help/one_screen/le.htmLinks ]

BLS (2021b). Consumer Price Index Historical Tables for U.S. City Average. Bureau of Labor Statistics. [ Links ]

BBVA Bancomer-SGConapo (2021). Anuario de Migración y Remesas México 2021. Fundación BBVA Bancomer, A.C. y Secretaría General del Consejo Nacional de Población, de la Secretaría de Gobernación del Gobierno de México. [ Links ]

Castillo, R. (2001). “Remesas: un análisis de cointegración para el caso de México”, Frontera Norte, Vol. 13 (26). [ Links ]

Clemente, J., Montañes, A. & Reyes, M. (1998). Testing for a Unit Root in variables with a double change in the mean. Economics Letters 59: 175-182. [ Links ]

Cuecuecha, A., Fuentes-Mayorga, N. and McLeod, D. (2021). Do minimum wage differentials help explain declining U.S. Mexico migration? Migraciones Internacionales (forthcoming). [ Links ]

Djajic, S. (1989). Migrants in a Guest-Worker System: A Utility Maximizing Approach. Journal of Development Economics, 3: 327-339. https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-3878(89)90017-5 [ Links ]

Djajic, S. and Milbourne, R. (1988). A General Equilibrium Model of Guest-Worker Migration: The Source Country Perspective, Journal of International Economics, 25: 335-351. https://doi.org/10.1016/0022-1996(88)90059-1 [ Links ]

Domínguez, C. and Miranda, D. (2021). Dinámica del flujo de remesas durante la pandemia del Covid-19. Estudios Económicos CNBV-Volumen 4. https://www.gob.mx/cms/uploads/attachment/file/638278/7._Dinamica_de_las_remesas_durante_la_pandemia.pdfLinks ]

Eggers, A., Tuñon, G. & Dafoe, A. (2021). Placebo Tests for Causal Inference. Working Paper. Department of Political Science. University of Chicago. [ Links ]

Elbadawi, I. & R. de R. Rocha (1992). “Determinants of Expatriate Workers’ Remittances in North Afric adn Europe”, Banco Mundial, Documento de trabajo núm. 1038. [ Links ]

El-Sakka & McNabb (1999). “The Macroeconomic Determinants of Migrant Remittances”, World Development, Vol. 27(8). https://doi.org/10.1016/s0305-750x(99)00067-4 [ Links ]

Engle, R.F. & Granger, C.W.J. (1987). Cointegration and error Correction: Representation, Estimation and Testing. Econometrica 55 : 251-276. [ Links ]

Faini, R. (1994). Worker’s Remittances and the Real Exchange Rate: A Quantitative Framework”, Journal of Population Economics, Vol. 7. [ Links ]

Federal Reserve Economic Data (FRED, 2021). Current Price Adjusted GDP Monthly Index Not Seasonally Adjusted. Economic Research Division. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. Available at: https://fred.stlouisfed.orgLinks ]

Giuliano, P. & M. Ruiz-Arranz (2005). Remittances, Financial Development and Growth. Fondo Monetario Internacional. Documento de trabajao núm. 05/234. https://doi.org/10.5089/9781451862539.001 [ Links ]

Gupta, P. (2005). “Macroeconomic Determinants of Remittances: Evidence from India”, WP/05/224. Working Papers, IMF. https://doi.org/10.5089/9781451862430.001 [ Links ]

INEGI (2021a). PIB y Cuentas Nacionales. Estimación Oportuna. https://www.inegi.org.mx/temas/pibo/#Links ]

INEGI (2021b). Índice Nacional de Precios al Consumidor. https://www.inegi.org.mx/temas/inpc/Links ]

Islas, A. & S. Moreno (2011). “Determinantes del flujo de remesas en México, un análisis empírico”, EconoQuantum, Vol. 7, Núm. 2, pp. 9-36. https://doi.org/10.18381/eq.v7i2.113 [ Links ]

Johansen, S. (1991). Estimation and hypothesis testing of cointegration vectors in Gaussian vector autorregresive models. Econometrica 59: 1551-80. [ Links ]

Lucas, R.E.B. and O. Stark (1985). Motivations to remit: Evidence from Botswana, Journal of Political Economy , 93, 5: 901-18. https://doi.org/10.1086/261341 [ Links ]

Mandelan, F. & Vilán, D. (2020). Remittances and COVID-19: A Tale of Two Countries. FED Notes. Washington Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, https://doi.org/10.17016/2380-7172.2803. [ Links ]

Mendoza-Gonzalez, M.A. & Villagra-Piña, A. (2021). Effects of Covid 19 and people mobility constraint on addictive consumption of cigarettes in Mexico, 2005-2020. Revista Mexicana de Economía y Finanzas, Nueva Época 16, (3):1-20. [ Links ]

Miranda, K. (1988). Workers, Remittances, Commodity Aid Utilization and Exchange Rate Unification, Fondo Monetario Internacional, Documento de Trabajo. [ Links ]

Mouhoub, E.M., J. Oudinet & E. Unan (2008). “Macroeconomic Determinants of Migrant’s Remittances in the Southern and Eastern Mediterranean Countries”, Centre d’Economie de L’Université de Paris Nord, Séminarie Demographie, Employ et Migrations entre les rives de la Mediterranée , Université Paris Nord et GDRI DREEM- CNRS, 2º. borrador. https://doi.org/10.3166/lcn.9.2.137-161 [ Links ]

Osili, U.O. (2004) Migrants and Housing Investment: Theory and Evidence from Nigeria. Economic Development and Cultural Change 52 (4): 821-849. https://doi.org/10.1086/420903 [ Links ]

Phillips, P.C.B. & Perron, P. (1988). Testing for a Unit Root in Time Series Regression. Biometrika 75: 335-346. [ Links ]

Ramírez, T. & Lozano, F. (2021). Vulnerabilidad de la población migrante de México frente a la pandemia del COVID-19. Revista Latinoamericana de Población, vol. 15, núm. 28, pp. 102_134, https://www.redalyc.org/journal/3238/323864536004/html/ https://doi.org/10.31406/relap2021.v15.i1.n28.4 [ Links ]

Rapoport, H. & Docquier, F. (2005). The Economics of Migrants’ Remittances. In L.A. Gerard-Varet, S-C Kolm and J. Mercier (Eds) Handbook of the Economics of Reciprocity, Giving and Altruism (Amsterdam: North Holland). https://doi.org/10.1016/s1574-0714(06)02017-3 [ Links ]

Solimano, A. (2001). “International Migration and the Global Economic Order: An Overview”, World Bank Policy, Documento de trabajo núm. 2720. [ Links ]

Stark, O. and R.E.B. Lucas (1988). Migration, Remitances, and the Family. Economic Development and Cultural Change , 36: 465-481. https://doi.org/10.1086/451670 [ Links ]

Stark, O. , E. Taylor, and S. Yitzhaki (1986). Remittances and Inequality. The Economic Journal, 96: 722-740. https://doi.org/10.2307/2232987 [ Links ]

Swamy, G. (1981). “International Migrant Workers’ Remittaces Issues and Prospects”, Banco Mundial. Documento de trabajo núm. 481. [ Links ]

U.S. Department of the Treasury (2021). Dayly Treasury Bill Rates Data. https://www.treasury.gov/resource-center/data-chart-center/interest-rates/Pages/TextView.aspx?data=billratesLinks ]

Valdivia, M., M.A. Mendoza, L. Quintana, C. Salas & F. Lozano (2020). Impacto de la COVID en las remesas y sus efectos contracíclicos en las economías regionales en México, Contaduría y Administración, 65(5), Especial COVID-19, 2020, 1-14. https://doi.org/10.22201/fca.24488410e.2020.3025 [ Links ]

Vargas Silva, C. & Huang, P. (2005). “Macroeconomic Determinants of Workers’ Remittances: Host versus Home Country’s Economic Conditions”, Journal of International Trade & Economic Development, Vol. 15(1): 81-99. https://doi.org/10.1080/09638190500525779 [ Links ]

Wagner, M. & Wied, D. (2017). Consistent monitoring of cointegration relationships: The US housing market and the subprime crisis. Journal of Time Series Analysis. DOI. 10.1111/jtsa.12247 [ Links ]

World Bank (2021). Migration and Development Brief 34, May 2021. https://www.knomad.org/publication/migration-and-development-brief-34Links ]

* No source of funding for research development

1The flow of remittances to low- and middle-income countries fell 1.6 percent between 2019 and 2020, falling from 548 to 540 dollar billion (World Bank, 2021).

2The altruism motive is that the migrant's utility function is affected by the happiness derived from his own consumption and from the utility of others. The exchange motive consists of exchange situations that imply remittances and that constitute Pareto improvements, such as the purchase of services such as the care of the migrant's assets (e.g. land, livestock) or family members (children, elderly parents) at home; the strategic reason is that remittances can be part of a strategic interaction within the family of migrants, so that remittances can be a bribe for the less qualified to stay at home; and the inheritance motive is that remittances are an investment strategy in inheritance on the part of the migrant and a control device to ensure remittances on the part of the family. The reason for insurance and non-pecuniary damage is that the migrants would insure the remaining members of the family against the fall in rural income and would give them support in case of unemployment or retirement, and that families, because they know their members well, they can choose migrants who combine high potential earnings and high degrees of loyalty; the investment and loan payment motive explains remittances as repayment of loans on investment in migration, conceived as a form of human capital formation (Rapoport and Docquier, 2005).

3The “impure altruism” consists of a model that combines the pure altruism represented through the contribution of a person to a public good through their generosity and the private benefits obtained from their generosity per se, characterized as a “warm glow” (Andreoni, 1989).

4“Enlightened selfishness” is a model of altruism tempered or enlightened by the self-interest of migrants, in which remittances are an element of the voluntary compliance arrangement between the migrant and his family (Lucas and Stark, 1985).

5We thank an anonymous referee for signaling out this point to us.

6We also explored using monthly dummies in the estimation, but they did not make a difference in the main results.

7Further analysis demonstrate that the first difference of the remittances distributes as normal, since a Jarque-Bera test obtains a Chi-squared of .345, which implies that the null of normality cannot be rejected. Similarly, a Lagrange Multiplier test obtains a Chi squared of 69 for the first lag and a Chi squared of 56 for the second lag, which implies that at the 5% confidence level we reject the null of potential first order and second order autocorrelation in the residuals of the VEC. Stability tests show that the eigen values of the VEC system lay inside the unit circle, and consequently the system is stable.

8All coefficients for other equations for each of the four VEC estimations are available from the authors upon request.

Received: April 10, 2021; Revised: December 02, 2021; Accepted: February 02, 2022; Published: June 08, 2022

+ Corresponding author. Profesor Investigador, Facultad de Economía, Universidad Popular Autónoma del Estado de Puebla, miguel.cruz@upaep.mx, 17 Sur 901, Barrio de Santiago, Puebla, Pue., C.P. 72410, tel. 2223900347.

Creative Commons License This is an open-access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License