SciELO - Scientific Electronic Library Online

 
vol.14 número4Impacto de la rentabilidad y la cuota de mercado en las empresas zombis en México índice de autoresíndice de assuntospesquisa de artigos
Home Pagelista alfabética de periódicos  

Serviços Personalizados

Journal

Artigo

Indicadores

Links relacionados

  • Não possue artigos similaresSimilares em SciELO

Compartilhar


Revista mexicana de economía y finanzas

versão On-line ISSN 2448-6795versão impressa ISSN 1665-5346

Rev. mex. econ. finanz vol.14 no.4 Ciudad de México Out./Dez. 2019  Epub 21-Fev-2020

https://doi.org/10.21919/remef.v14i4.389 

Artículos de investigación

Social Weights and the Regional Allocation of Inter-Governmental Transfers

Pesos Sociales y Asignación Regional de Transferencias Intergubernamentales

Raúl Alberto Ponce Rodríguez1  * 
http://orcid.org/0000-0003-0851-2687

Benito Alan Ponce Rodríguez1  ** 
http://orcid.org/0000-0003-4550-2103

1Universidad Autónoma de Ciudad Juárez, México


Abstract

We develop an optimal theory of intergovernmental transfers and a simulation analysis that provides estimates of the optimal shares of resources to be allocated to state governments in Mexico. Our models provide several insights: First, the best fit of our model to observed data suggests that the best predictor of the share of intergovernmental transfers to states is the density of population in Mexico. Second, our analysis provides recommendations of economic policy design by estimating the optimal shares of intergovernmental transfers to states in Mexico. Our analysis is the first to develop estimates of intergovernmental transfers by using Paretian distribution functions of the interregional distribution of income and the interregional distribution of preferences for local public spending. Our estimates help to understand advantages and shortcomings of the current system of allocation of intergovernmental transfers and propose an alternative way to allocate intergovernmental transfers that couldimprove the welfare associated with local public spending in Mexico.

Keywords: Intergovernmental transfers; fiscal federalism; income distribution; efficiency; heterogeneity of preferences

JEL Classification: H7; H77; O15; H21

Resumen

Desarrollamos una teoría de transferencias intergubernamentales optimas y un análisis de simulación que nos permite estimar las transferencias óptimas de recursos del gobierno central a los gobiernos estatales en México. Nuestros resultados son: Primero, nuestros modelos demuestran que el mejor predictor de las transferencias intergubernamentales observadas en México es la densidad poblacional. Segundo, nuestro trabajo provee recomendaciones de política económica al proporcionar estimaciones sobre la proporción óptima de transferencias intergubernamentales a los estados en México. Nuestro análisis es el primero en desarrollar estimaciones de las transferencias intergubernamentales al utilizar funciones paramétricas Paretianas de la distribución regional del ingreso y las preferencias inter-regionales por el gasto público local. Nuestras estimaciones ayudan a entender las ventajas y desventajas del sistema actual de transferencias y, adicionalmente, propone una alternativa de asignación de las transferencias intergubernamentales que podría mejorar el bienestar asociado con el gasto público local en México.

Keywords: entrepreneurship; global innovation index; human talent; search and matching with frictions

JEL Classification: J01; J23; J24; M51; O31

1.Introduction

Empirical evidence shows that the vast majority of central governments in modern economies use inter-governmental transfers (monetary transfers from the central government to subnational governments) to finance goods and services provided by subnational governments. Intergovernmental transfers are used in modern economies for different reasons: first, local public goods provided by subnational governments might show positive regional externalities. In the absence of intergovernmental transfers, local governments might not recognize the external benefits of local public goods and the provision of local public goods is not Pareto efficient. The central government can design a system of transfers to create incentives for local governments to provide Pareto efficient levels of local public goods (see Boadway 2007).

Second, intergovernmental transfers can be used to redistribute resources and reduce the inequality in the distribution of access to critical government services for individuals living in different regions of a country. Subnational governments might have different abilities to provide goods and services to their residents. This might lead to a problem of horizontal inequality in the access of residents of different localities to goods and services provided by sub-national governments such as public education, public security and health services (see Martinez and Sepulveda 2011). Therefore, a program of intergovernmental transfers can redistribute resources from high income to low income localities to improve the quality and access of critical services from the government in all regions of the country. Third, intergovernmental transfers can be explained as a mechanism to share revenue across different subnational governments (see Rao 2007) and to reduce failures of coordination that could lead to vertical and horizontal tax externalities (see Ponce and Medina 2018).

In Mexico, the provision of goods and services of sub-national governments is highly dependent of resources transferred by the central government to state governments. The evidence shows that, in 2014, the proportion of intergovernmental transfers in relation of total state public revenues is 84% (similar estimates are found for other years). According to a report of World Bank (2019), the total amount of intergovernmental transfers in Mexico is approximately 8.1 percent of GDP in 2017. In practice, Mexico uses intergovernmental transfers for different purposes: for instance, the fund of “participaciones” is a revenue sharing program financed by federal taxes aiming to reduce significant vertical imbalances (see the report by World Bank 2019).3 Intergovernmental transfers also include conditional transfers (through the fund of aportaciones) that financespecific projects in the areas of health, public security, etc., and discretionary transfers though specific agreements or convenios to finance the perceived priorities of policy makers in the central and state governments (see the report by World Bank 2019).

Given the importance of intergovernmental transfers in Mexico, it is relevant to ask: what should be the optimal distribution of inter-governmental transfers to state governments in Mexico? The objective of this paper is to develop a theoretical model to answer this question. We also develop a simulation analysis of the implied results of the theory to compare with the observed allocation of intergovernmental transfers in Mexico. Our analysis shows that the current system of allocation of intergovernmental transfers are poorly related with the regional inequality in the distribution of income and the regional heterogeneity of preferences of individuals for local public spending. However, most analysis on fiscal federalism, consider both, the regional distribution of income and the distribution of preferences, as important determinants of intergovernmental transfers. Hence, our analysis provides insights about advantages and shortcomings of the way intergovernmental transfers are currently allocated in Mexico. To see this, note that the first insight of our analysis shows that our model that considers a social welfare function in which all individuals of all regions receive the same weight in the social welfare function, provides a surprisingly good fit for the observed shares of transfers from the central government to states with our simulated results having a correlation of 0.9 with the observed shares of intergovernmental transfers received by states in Mexico.

Second, if the central government is concerned with the regional inequality of income then the implied shares of transfers to state governments are significantly different to the observed allocation of state transfers in Mexico. Altogether these findings suggest that the observed shares of intergovernmental transfers in Mexico are not fully incorporating the regional inequality of income. However, our estimates indeed consider the regional inequality of income in Mexico, and therefore, our estimates provide a complete set of estimates for transfers to states that could lead to a policy reform that improves the regional equity of public spending of state governments.

Third, we provide estimates of shares of intergovernmental transfers to state governments for the case in which policy is concerned about matching the provision of local public goods with the heterogeneity of preferences of individuals across regions in Mexico. For this case, we also provide exact estimates of the shares of resources that each state should receive and our analysis reveals opportunities for Pareto efficient improvements in the allocation of intergovernmental transfers to state governments in Mexico. In summary, our model identifies prescriptions of policy that could reform the way intergovernmental transfers are allocated in Mexico. Our policy prescriptions could lead to improvements of welfare in the Mexican economy related with a more effective subnational public spending.

The rest of the paper is structured as follows: section 2 provides a literature review. Section 3 introduces our theoretical model. Section 4 considers that the design of intergovernmental transfers seek to maximize a social welfare function that satisfies the properties of unanimity and symmetry in the allocation of social weights (all states receive the same social weight in the social welfare function). Section 5 estimates intergovernmental transfers for the case in which policymakers seek to reduce the regional inequality in the distribution of income. Section 6 considers social weights associated with the intensity of preferences for local public goods. Section 7 includes the description of the data and the simulation analysis that provides estimatesof optimal shares of intergovernmental transfers to state governments. Section 8 presents the results of our simulations. Section 9 concludes.

2. Literature Review

The literature on public economics on intergovernmental transfers can be classified by normative theories (that seek to study how policies should be designed and implemented) and positive theories (that study how polices are designed and implemented). Oneinfluential contribution on public finance is the median voter theory which postulates that government spending and taxation are determined by politicians that seek to win elections see Meltzer and Richard (1981). In this case, a central and sub-nationalgovernments design the ideal policy of the median voter on government spending and taxation because that is the policy that maximizes votes in the election. More recently, Hettich and Winer (2005) criticize the median voter model by pointing out that this model can not explain the complexity of modern tax systems and the multi-dimensional aspects of government spending. They propose a probabilistic voting model that predicts that policy makers deign tax and spending policies to please different groups in the society. Hence, governments select the ideal policy of the average voter or a weighted average voter in the electorate. Some applications to the theory of fiscal federalism from models with electoral concerns include the analysis of Besley and Coate(2003) who study the role of local and national legislatures in determining taxing and spending decisions of central and subnational governments and Lockwood (2008) who studies the role of lobbying in explaining the structure of governments in a federalist economy (for a survey of the political economy of fiscal federalism see Lockwood 2015). Recent empirical analysis, see Ponce, et al (2018) and Hankla, Martinez-Vazquez and Ponce-Rodriguez (2019) show worldwide robust evidence that elections and political institutions are important determinants of government spending in federations.

On the normative theory of fiscal public finance, the landmark theories of optimal taxation and optimal public spending consider that policy makers should design public policies to maximize a social welfare function which represents the collective welfareof society. While designing policy, policy makers, might assign weights to the welfare of individuals in the social welfare function. These social weights might represent well deserving objectives that policy makers want to achieve such as an equitable allocation of resources or concerns about the efficiency in the allocation of resources (see Atkinson and Stiglitz 1972, 1976 and more recently Saez and Stantcheva 2016). The normative analysis has emphasized that intergovernmental transfers should also be used to redistribute resources and reduce the inequality in the distribution of access to critical government services for individuals living in different regions of a country (see Boadway 2007). Subnational governments might have different abilities toprovide goods and services to their residents. This might lead to a problem of horizontal inequality in the access of residents of different localities to goods and services provided by sub-national governments such as public education, public security and health services (see Martinez and Sepulveda 2011). Others have pointed out that intergovernmental transfers should be assigned to achieve an efficient allocation of resources, see Boadway and Shah (2007). Intergovernmental transfers can also be explained as a mechanism to share revenue across different subnational governments (see Rao 2007) and to reduce failures of coordination that could lead to vertical and horizontal tax externalities (see Ponce-Rodriguez and Medina 2018).

Our analysis is a normative theory that allows to identify prescriptions of policy design by identifying optimal allocations for intergovernmental transfers. Our paper is different from the literature because we study the role of social weights in the social welfare function as a determinant of spending and tax policy design. The determination of weights takes into consideration the objectives of policy design of policy makers. Hence, the inter-regional allocation of weights might reflect priorities related with anti-poverty programs, concerns with the regional distribution of income and the efficiency in the allocation of resources. Hence, our theory contributes to the literature by considering specific Paretian regional distribution functions of social weights in the social welfare function and characterizing the optimal amount of intergovernmental transfers to states when policy makers are concerned about the regional inequality of income and the regional distribution of heterogeneity of preferences ofindividuals for local public spending.4

In addition, in this paper we develop a simulation analysis of the implied results our theory to compare with the observed allocation of intergovernmental transfers in Mexico. This comparison provides insights about advantages and shortcomings of the way intergovernmental transfers are currently allocated in Mexico. In particular, our analysis shows that the current system of allocation of intergovernmental transfers are poorly related with the regional inequality in the distribution of income and the regional heterogeneity of preferences of individuals for local public spending. However, most analysis on fiscal federalism, consider both, the regional distribution of income and the distribution of preferences, as important determinants of intergovernmental transfers. Hence, our analysis provides insights about advantages and shortcomings of the way intergovernmental transfers are currently allocated in Mexico.

3. The Model

The preferences and budget constraint of a resident living in locality i=1,2.I are characterized by the utility function of a representative household living in the locality, μi=xi+βiln(gi) , where xi is a private good, gi is a public good provided in locality i and βi>0 is a parameter measuring the intensity of preferences for the public good. The budget constraint of the representative household in locality i is xi=ei(1τi) where ei is an endowment and τi is a proportional income tax. The indirect utility of this individual is given by υi(ei,τi, gi)=ei(1τi)+βiln(gi) . Population in each of the localities is given by Ni i .

We consider an economy fiscally centralized in which there is a central government and I local governments. Spending and taxing decisions are determined by the central government while local governments are simple administrators of the provision of the public good on their localities. The central government collects tax revenue from all regions of the country by imposing a uniform proportional income tax τi=τ  i and determines intergovernmental transfers to finance local public goods inall regions. Hence Ti=gi  i where Ti  i is the intergovernmental transfer allocated from the central government to the local government of region i.

The central government selects {Ti}i=1I ,τ  i to maximize a nationwide social welfare function Ψ=i=1IΨi , which is the sum of utilities of residents of each region and Ψi=Ni υi(ei,τi, Ti) is the social welfare of region i. In designing policy, the central government considers the nationwide distribution of social benefits of local public goods and the nationwide social welfare costs associated with taxation. The government faces the following trade-offs in the design of intergovernmental transfers: On the one hand, a marginal increase in the income tax implemented by the central government reduces private consumption of all residents in the economy. This constitutes a social marginal cost.

On the other hand, the government collects tax revenue and redistributes resources in the economy through intergovernmental transfers that finance local public goods in the economy. This is the social marginal benefit. At equilibrium, the optimal level ofintergovernmental transfers in locality i is where the social marginal benefit of increasing local public spending in locality i is equal to the social marginal costs of taxation. The other trade-off for policy design is that the central government allocates resources through intergovernmental transfers taking into account that 1$ allocated in locality i has an opportunity cost equivalent to the marginal benefits of local public goods in neighbour localities.

Hence the problem of tax and intergovernmental transfer policy design is given by:

Max {Ti}i=1I ,τ      Ψ=i=1IΦiΨi (1)

s.t:  i)  Ψi=  Ni υi(ei,τi, gi) (2)

ii)   i=1ITi=τ i=1INiei (3)

iii)    Ti=gi   i (4)

Equation (1) is the nationwide social welfare which is the sum of the weighted social welfare functions of each localities Ψi i . In equation (1), Φi0 is the social marginal utility of the representative household living in locality i. This social weight shows the importance of a household living in locality i with endowment ei in the society, and therefore, it might reflect concerns (or tastes) of the policy maker over inter-regional income inequality and the inter-regional heterogeneity of preference for local public goods. Equation (3) is the budget constraint of the central government, the left hand side is the total amount of intergovernmental transfers allocated to all subnational governments and the right hand side are the public revenues of the central government. Equation (4) says that the intergovernmental transfers of the central government finances local public goods in all localities.

In what follows, we characterize the equilibrium level of inter-governmental transfers of the central government to subnational governments i=1,2I .

Proposition 1. The optimal allocation of inter-governmental transfers to subnational government in locality i is given by

Ti*=  ΦiNiβi {i=1INiei i=1IΦiNiei}     i (5)

Proof.

See appendix 1.

Proposition 1 says that the optimal allocation of inter-governmental transfers that finances local public spending in locality i depends positively on the country’s aggregate income, i=1INiei  , and the marginal social utility of local public spending on locality i, ΦiNiβi , and negatively on the country’s weighted aggregate income i=1IΦiNiei . The higher the country’s aggregate income the higher the tax revenue of the central government and the higher the intergovernmental transfers that finance public spending in all localities (including locality i). The higher the weighted aggregate income, i=1IΦiNiei , the higher the social marginal costs from income taxation and the lower is public spending in the whole country (including locality i). The higher the social marginal utility of public spending on locality i, ΦiNiβi , the higher the social marginal benefits of spending in the locality and the higher is Ti* . Note, that increases in the social marginal utility of residents of locality i in the social welfare of the central government, Φi , in the size of population of the locality i,Ni , and the intensity of preferences for public goods, βi , lead to increases in the marginal social utility of public spending on locality i, and consequently, in increases in intergovernmental transfers in the locality.

4. Social Weights and the Regional Allocation of Inter-Governmental Transfers

In this section, we analyse how the allocation of social weights determine the regional distribution of inter-governmental transfers and local public spending. The allocation of social weights in the social welfare function might be explained by preferences (or concerns) of policy makers over regional inequality, the distribution of regional preferences of citizens over local public goods, the regional distribution of population, etc. Even other incentives such as electoral concerns and political ideologymight affect the allocation of social weights, the regional distribution of intergovernmental transfers and the regional distribution of public spending.

In what follows, proposition 2 characterizes our benchmark outcome in which all households of all localities receive the same weight in the social welfare function of the central government. That is, Φi=Φj=Φ  ij . This case reflects a symmetry in the way households, living in different regions, are treated by the central government. In this case, the social welfare function of the central government is considered to satisfy the unanimity and symmety properties in which all households have the same marginal social utility.5

Proposition 2. If Φi=Φj=Φ  ij then the optimal allocation of inter-governmental transfers is given by

Ti*=Niβi       i (6)

Proof.

Result follows trivially from proposition 1.

Proposition 2 says that if the central government assigns the same weight to the welfare of all individuals in the economy in the social welfare function from then the optimal allocation of inter-governmental transfers that finances local public spending in all localities depend only on the regional distribution of social marginal benefits of local spending in each locality, Niβi . That is to say, localities with higher than average marginal utility of government spending should receive higher thanaverage intergovernmental transfers. In this economy, localities with higher than average population and higher than average preferences for local public goods should receive higher than average transfers and the size of local public spending should alsobe higher than the nationwide average.

5. Inter-Regional Income Inequality, Social Weights with Equity Concerns and Government Spending

The policy maker might be concerned about the inter-regional inequality of income. This might be an issue of main concern for policy design because different regions might have different incomes and therefore different capacities to provide local public goods such as public infrastructure, education, health services and other important tasks in which the government is involved. Hence, wealthy regions might be able to afford essential public spending that affects positively the welfare of their residents while poor regions would be constrained to have access to local resources to finance public spending. This, in turn, will lead to an unequal distribution of local public spending and welfare of residents in the economy. For this reason, a policy maker might assign priorities on the regional allocation of inter-governmental transfers to design an equalization transfer policy in which wealthy regions redistribute income to poor regions.

More relevant for our analysis, is that the policy maker in the central government could have a taste for the regional inequality of income. This “taste” corresponds to the personal view of the policy maker of the central government over the issue of the regional inequality of income in the economy. For instance, the policy maker in the central government might believe that one of the objectives of designing intergovernmental transfers is to maximize the redistribution of welfare of individuals livingin different regions. Such a personal view of the policy maker in the central government would imply a very particular set of social weights in the social welfare function in which localities with low income receive a high social weight in the social welfare function. In this case, the regional equitable distribution of income would be a clear objective in the allocation of intergovernmental transfers.

One way to do so, is to assign specific weights to the regional distribution of marginal benefits of public spending. To do so, a policy maker could assign weights according to a Paretian distribution of income in which localities with low income might beassigned a high social weight in the social welfare function (see figure 1). In particular, the policy maker might assign weights that are inversely related to income in the locality. To characterize such possibility, we define eimin=Min{e1,e2eI} therefore eimin represents the lowest income in the economy. The allocation of social weights in the social welfare function of the government motivated by inter-regional equity concerns is given as follows (see figure 1):

Φi={eiminei         eieimin   0            ei<eimin  (7)

Figure 1 Paretian Distribution of Income  

In condition (7), the policy maker assigns weights that are inversely related to income in the locality. Those localities with lower than average income have a social marginal utility (a social weight Φi ) higher than the average nationwide social marginal utility in the welfare function of the central government. Proposition 3 characterizes the distribution of intergovernmental transfers for the case policy design seeks to reduce the regional inequality of income.

Proposition 3. If the allocation of social weights is determined by equity concerns about the inter-regional distribution of income such that

Φi={eiminei         eieimin    0            ei<eimin

Then the optimal allocation of inter-governmental transfers is denoted by TiP* such that

 TiP*=  Niβi {Ef(ei)ei}       i (8)

Where Ef(ei)=i=1Ifiei is a weighted average of per capita income in locality i, and fi is the density of population in locality i over the nationwide population such that

fi(0,1]:fi=Nii=1INi     i=1Ifi=1 (9)

Proof.

See the appendix.

If the policy maker is concerned with the interregional inequality of income then the allocation of transfers for locality i depend on the aggregate intensity of preferences in locality i, Niβi , which in turn depends positively on the population of the locality, Ni , and the intensity of preferences of locality i over local public goods βi . The transfer in each locality also depends positively on the relative measure of weighted income in the country and the income of locality i, Ef(ei)ei , the higher the income in the locality i, in relation of the weighted nationwide average income, the lower the transfer in the locality.

Proposition 4 makes a comparative analysis of the distribution of transfers to locality i for the case in which the social weights reflect that the policy maker assigns the same social weight to all households, that is Ti* , and for the case in which the policy maker has concerns about an equitable inter-regional allocation of resources in the country, TiP* .

Proposition 4. If the allocation of social weights is determined by an Inter-Rional Paretian distribution of income given by

Φi={eiminei         eieimin   0            ei<eimin 

And if a locality i satisfies

ei Ef(ei)     then     TiP*  Ti* (10)

Proof.

This outcome follows trivially from propositions one and three.

Proposition 4 shows that if the allocation of social weights in policy design is not trivial. In particular, proposition 4 shows that if the policy maker is concerned about the inter-regional inequality of welfare of citizens then those localities with incomes that are lower to the socially weighted income Ef(ei) will receive higher transfers relative the situation in which all households have the same inter-regional social weight in the social welfare function, that is to say, if ei  Ef(ei) then TiP*  Ti* .

6. Social Weights According to the Inter-Regional Distribution of Preferences and Intergovernmental Transfers

Policy makers might have preferences (or might be concerned) about the inter-regional heterogeneity of preferences. This might be an issue of main concern for policy makers because different regions might have different intensities of preferences for local public goods. Optimal inter-governmental transfers are required to recognize the regional intensity of preferences for local public spending. To see this, note that localities with residents with higher than average marginal utilities from public spending (in our model, localities with higher than average values of βi ) will also have higher than average social marginal benefits from public spending. An optimal allocation of intergovernmental transfers requires that the higher is the marginal utility of public spending in the locality the higher should be the transfer to that locality, otherwise, local public spending would be sub-optimal.

As we mentioned before, also relevant for our analysis is that the policy maker in the central government could have a taste for the heterogeneity of preferences of individuals for subnational spending. This “taste” corresponds to the personal view ofthe policy maker of the central government over the issue of the heterogeneity of preferences for subnational public spending in the economy. For instance, the policy maker in the central government might believe that the provision of public goods shouldbe uniform across localities. Such a personal view of the policy maker in the central government would imply a very particular set of social weights in the social welfare function, however, such prescription of policy might not be socially optimal for the general case of the problem of the allocation of intergovernmental transfers.

Another possibility is that the policy maker wants to make the most efficient decisions in designing policy in the central government. Therefore, localities with high social marginal benefits from public spending could receive a high social weigh in the social welfare function. In this case, maximizing the regional net fiscal incidence of public goods (the net gains from government intervention) would be a clear objective in the allocation of intergovernmental transfers. The net fiscal incidence reflects the society’s surplus from government intervention and recognizes the next economic tradeoff: on the one hand, a marginal increase in the income tax implemented by the central government reduces private consumption of all residents in the economy. This constitutes a social marginal cost. On the other hand, the government collects tax revenue and redistributes resources in the economy through intergovernmental transfers that finances local public goods in the economy. This is the social marginal benefit.

Hence, the net fiscal incidence is the net benefit-cost analysis from government intervention and represents the society’s economic surplus (the sum of the consumer’s and producer’s surplus). By assigning social weights to the social welfare function, the policy maker is assigning weights to the net fiscal incidence of localities. Therefore, different weights to the net fiscal incidence of government intervention in each locality will lead to different levels of nationwide social welfare. For instance, if the policy maker assigns a high weight to localities with high net fiscal incidence then the nationwide welfare would be higher relative the alternative in which the policy maker assigns a high weight to localities with low net fiscal incidence.

Taking into account the regional distribution of net fiscal incidence of government intervention, policy makers can assign weights that are positively related with the intensity of preferences in each locality, that is to say, localities with high net fiscal incidence from local public goods should be assigned a high social weight in the social welfare function (see equation 10). To characterize such possibility, we define the locality with the highest parameter of intensity of preferences for public spending by βimax=Max{β1,β2βI} . In this case, the allocation of weights for each locality Φi satisfies the following:

Φi={βiβimax         βiβimax    0           βi>βimax (11)

We also define, Eh(βi)=i=1Ihiβi , as the nationwide weighted average of the parameter of intensity of preferences βi and hi(ei) as the share of income in locality i over the nationwide income, satisfying:

hi(ei)(0,1]: hi(ei)=Nieii=1INiei      i=1Ihi(ei)=1 (12)

In what follows, proposition 5 characterizes the size of inter-governmental transfers Tiβ* for the case in which social weights are assigned to incorporate the heterogeneity of preferences over local public spending and proposition 6 compares Tiβ* with the case in which the policy maker assigns the same social weight to all households, that is, Ti* .

Proposition 5. If the allocation of social weights is determined by an inter-regional Paretian distribution of preferences given by

Φi={βiβimax         βiβimax    0           βi>βimax

Then the optimal allocation of inter-governmental transfers is denoted by Tiβ* such that

Tiβ*= Niβi {βiEh(βi)}       i (13)

Where Eh(βi)=i=1Ihiβi , is the nationwide weighted average of the parameter of intensity of preferences for localities and

hi(ei)(0,1]: hi(ei)=Nieii=1INiei     i=1Ihi(ei)=1 (14)

Proof.

See the appendix.

Proposition 5, says that for the case in which the inter-regional heterogeneity of preferences for local public goods determines the allocation of social weights Φi , the distribution of inter-governmental transfers Tiβ* depends positively on the aggregate intensity of preferences in locality i, Niβi , and on the ratio of the parameter of intensity of preferences of locality i in relation to the nationwide average intensity of preferences in the economy given by βiEh(βi) .

Proposition 6 compares Tiβ* with the case in which the policy maker assigns the same social weight to all households, that is, Ti* .

Proposition 6. If the allocation of social weights is determined by an Inter-regional Paretian distribution of preferences given by

Φi={  βiβimax         βiβimax     0           βi>βimax 

And if a locality i satisfies

βi  Eh(βi)    then    Tiβ*  Ti* (15)

Proof.

This outcome follows by comparing Tiβ* from proposition 5 and Ti* from proposition 2.

Proposition 6 shows that if the policy maker is concerned about the inter-regional heterogeneity of preferences for local public spending then those localities with values of βi that are higher to the weighted value of the intensity of preferences for local public spending Eh(βi)=i=1Ihiβi will receive higher transfers relative the situation in which all households have the same inter-regional social weight in the social welfare function, that is to say, if βi  Eh(βi) then Tiβ*  Ti* .

7. Simulations and Estimates of Optimal Shares of Inter-Governmental Transfers

Our theory makes predictions over the size and regional distribution of intergovernmental transfers. In particular, table 1 shows predictions of our theory for the optimal allocation of inter-governmental transfers (see column B of table 1) and its implied shares of intergovernmental transfers in relation to the total amount of resources devoted from the central government to state governments (see column C of table 1). The shares of intergovernmental transfers are defined as follows, consider Ti* as the amount of inter-governmental transfers allocated by the central government to the government of state i. The share of inter-governmental transfers in the state is given by si*=Ti* i=1ITi*  where i=1ITi*  is the total amount of resources devoted from the central government to state governments.6

Based on our theoretical model, we provide estimates for the size and regional distribution of shares of intergovernmental transfers to state governments for the cases in which the central government is concerned about the regional inequality in the distribution of income and the regional heterogeneity of preferences for local public goods. We also provide estimates for the case in which the social welfare function satisfies the properties of unanimity and symmetry (all social weights are the same).

For the analysis of simulation, we use data for intergovernmental transfers, Ti* , as the sum of “participaciones” and “aportaciones” from the central government to state governments for year 2014, the state population in locality i for year 2014 (which is Ni ), the real state gross domestic product of locality i for year 2014 (which in our model is ei ), and for the parameter of intensity of preferences we use the proportion of women with superior education for year 2014 (women with acollege degree). Empirical evidence shows that the characteristics of population in the locality matter to determine the demand of local public spending. In particular, the larger the proportion of women and the larger the education of residents the higher is the demand for public spending, see Ferris (1983), Bergstrom, Rubinfeld and Perry Shapiro (1982), Holsey and Borcherding (1997), among many others. Hence we use the proportion of women with a college degree in state i as a proxi of taste for goodsand services provided by the state government. The higher the proportion of women with college degree the higher the intensity of preferences for goods and services from the government and the higher the demand for subnational public spending. The sourceof our data is Instituto Nacional de Estadistica, Geografia e Informatica (INEGI).

Table 1 Optimal Inter-Governmental Transfers and Optimal Shares of Inter-Governmental Transfers.  

Principles of Policy Design Social Weights (A) Optimal Transfers and Government Spending, Ti* (B) Shares of Inter-Governmental Transfers, si*=Ti* i=1ITi*  (C)
Unanimity and Symmetry (equal weights)
Φi=Φj=Φ  ij
Ti*=Niβi
si*=Niβii=1INiβi
Regional Inequality of Income
Φi={eimineieieimin0ei<eimin
TiP*=NiβiEf(ei)ei
siP*=Niβieii=1INiβiei
Regional Heterogeneity of Preferences
Φi={βiβimaxβiβimax0βi>βimax
Tiβ*=Ni(βi)2Eh(βi)
siβ*=Ni(βi)2i=1INi(βi)2

In what follows, figure two shows the distributional allocation of state gross domestic product for Mexico for year 2014, figure three the state distributions of regional heterogeneity of preferences for year 2014, and figure four the state population foryear 2014.

Figure 2 State Gross Domestic Product in Mexico, 2014 (Millions of pesos).  

Figure 3 Percentage of Women With College Education, 2014.  

Figure 4 Percentage of Women With College Education, 2014.  

8. Results

In this section, we present the results of our estimations based on our theoretical model. In the appendix we show a summary of all of our simulations (see table 5). Figure 5 and 6 show the observed share of inter-governmental transfers and the estimated shares of intergovernmental transfers for the case in which policy makers use social weights given by Φi=Φj=Φij . In this case, the social welfare function of the central government is considered to satisfy the unanimity and symmetric properties in which all households have the same marginal social utility. Our estimates of the shares of inter-governmental transfers are given by Si*=NiβiΣi=1INiβi (see table 1). As figure 6 shows, the estimates from the theoretical model are surprisingly close to the observed intergovernmental transfers received by states in 2014. The correlation between the real shares and our estimates assuming weights of the social welfare reflecting the principles of unanimity and symmetry is 0.9. However, we estimate the shares of intergovernmental transfers using only the regional density of population and assuming that all individuals in all regions have the same preferences for public spending. These estimates havea correlation with the observed data of 0.98. This means that the best fit of our model to observed data suggests that the best predictor of the share of intergovernmental transfers to states is the regional density of population in Mexico.

Figure 5 Real and Estimated Shares of Inter-Governmental Transfers by State When Social Weights Reflect Principles of Unanimity and Symmetry  

Table 2 shows the main winners and losers from a change in the allocation of intergovernmental transfers from the current system towards using social weights in the social welfare function satisfying the unanimity and symmetry properties in which all households have the same marginal social utility are Ciudad de Mexico, Estado de Mexico, Jalisco, and Nuevo Leon with gains in percentage points of 5.87 1.63, 1.20, and 1.11 of the total amount of resources devoted to intergovernmental transfers (see table 2).7 Clearly, the gains would be concentrated in Ciudad de Mexico and these gains would come to the expense of several states that would receive less intergovernmental transfers. In particular, the states that would lose intergovernmental transfers would be Chiapas (with a loss of 2.45 percentage points), Oaxaca (with a loss of 1.98 percentage points), Guerrero (with a loss of 1.58 percentage points) and Michoacan (with a loss of 0.99 percentage points), Guanajuanto (with a loss of 0.92 percentage points) and Tabasco (with a loss of 0.78 percentage points).

Table 2 Winners and Loser from the Current System Towards a Change of Social Weights Satisfying Unanimity and Symmetry Treatment from the Central Government  

State Social Weights with Unanimity and Symmetry Real Share of Intergov Transfers Gain State Social Weights with Unanimity and Symmetry Real Share of Intergov Transfers Loss
Ciudad de México 12.61 6.74 5.87 Chiapas 2.60 5.05 -2.45
Estado de México 13.41 11.73 1.68 Oaxaca 2.07 3.98 -1.91
Jalisco 6.65 5.45 1.20 Guerrero 2.13 3.70 -1.58
Nuevo León 5.31 4.21 1.11 Michoacán 2.78 3.77 -0.99
Baja California 3.08 2.29 0.79 Guanajuato 3.43 4.35 -0.92
Coahuila 2.82 2.34 0.48 Tabasco 1.97 2.74 -0.78

Figure 7 shows the observed shares of inter-governmental transfers and the estimated shares of intergovernmental transfers for the case in which policy makers are concerned with the regional inequality in the distribution of state income. In this case, our estimates of the shares of inter-governmental transfers are given by siP*=Niβieii=1INiβiei (see table 1). Figure 7 shows several aspects that are relevant to point out: first, the estimates from the theoretical model are undoubtedly different to the observed intergovernmental transfers received by states in 2014. The average estimated share of intergovernmental transfers to be received by state governments for the case social weights reflect concerns over inequality of income is 3.30 and the variance of the distribution is 0.83. In contrast, the observed share of transfers received by state governments is 3.32 and the variance of the distribution is 5.01.

The difference in the variance between the observed and estimated shares means that a change towards using social weights determined according to a concern of policy makers with the regional inequality of income leads to a more equitable allocation of intergovernmental transfers across regions. Second, the correlation between the real shares and the estimates assuming weights of the social welfare reflect concerns about the regional inequality in the distribution of income is 0.24.

What this means, is that policy makers in Mexico does not seem to incorporate (in a significant way) the regional inequality in the distribution of state income in the allocation of inter-governmental transfers to state governments. If policy makers were to consider the regional inequality of income the observed transfers would have less variability over localities.

Figure 6 Real and Estimated Shares of Inter-Governmental Transfers by State When Social Weights Reflect Concerns About the Regional Inequality of Income  

Table 3 shows the main winners and losers from a change in the allocation of intergovernmental transfers from the current system towards using social weights in the social welfare function according to a concern of policy makers with the regional inequality of income. The states with the gains in the allocation of intergovernmental transfers are Tlaxcala, Nayarit, Colima, Morelos, Baja California Sur and Yucatan with gains in percentage points, respectively, of 3.72, 3.28, 2.70, 2.39, 2.09 and 1.63 of thetotal amount of resources for intergovernmental transfers.

Table 3 Winners and Losers from a Change from the Current System Towards Social Weights Considering the Regional Inequality of Income  

State Social Weights Based on Inequality of Income Real Share of Intergov Transfers Gain State Social Weights Based on Inequality of Income Real Share of Intergov Transfers Loss
Tlaxcala 4.87 1.15 3.72 Estado de México 4.31 11.73 -7.42
Nayarit 4.50 1.22 3.28 Ciudad de México 2.09 6.74 -4.65
Colima 3.52 0.83 2.70 Veracruz 3.27 6.19 -2.92
Morelos 3.93 1.54 2.39 Jalisco 2.83 5.45 -2.62
Baja California Sur 2.89 0.80 2.09 Nuevo León 2.07 4.21 -2.14
Yucatán 3.43 1.80 1.63 Guanajuato 2.50 4.35 -1.85

The states that would lose from a change towards using social weights in a social welfare function according to a concern of policy makers with the regional inequality of income are Estado de Mexico (with a loss of 7.42 percentage points), Ciudad de Mexico (with a loss of 4.65 percentage points), Veracruz (with a loss of 3.27 percentage points), Jalisco (with a loss of 2.67 percentage points), Nuevo León (with a loss of 2.14 percentage points), and Guanajuato (with a loss of 1.85 percentage points).

Figure 8 shows the observed shares of inter-governmental transfers and the estimated shares of intergovernmental transfers for the case in which policy makers are concerned with the regional heterogeneity of preferences. That is to say, policy makers could assign weights that are positively related to localities with high marginal social benefits from local public goods and low marginal social costs from taxation.

Figure 7 Real and Estimated Shares of Inter-Governmental Transfers by State When Social Weights Reflect Concerns About the Regional Heterogeneity of Preferences  

In this case, our estimates of the shares of inter-governmental transfers are given by siβ*=Ni(βi)2i=1INi(βi)2 (see table 1). Figure 8 also shows that the distribution of intergovernmental transfers leads to more variance in the regional distribution of intergovernmental transfers and concentrates the gains in Ciudad de Mexico. The average share of transfers received by state governments is 2.85 and the variance of the distribution is 14.77 and the observed share of transfers received by state governments is 3.32 and the variance of the distribution is 5.01. Furthermore, the correlation between the real shares and the estimates (assuming weights of the social welfare reflect concerns about the regional inequality in the distribution of income) is 0.72.

Table 4 Winners and Loser from the Current System Towards a Change of Social Weights Considering Regional Heterogeneity 

State Shares of Inter-Gov Transfers Under Heterogeneity of Preferences Real Share of Intergov Transfers Gain State Shares of Inter-Gov Transfers Under Heterogeneity of Preferences Real Share of Intergov Transfers Loss
Ciudad de México 20.12 6.74 13.38 Chiapas 1.46 5.05 -3.59
Nuevo León 6.30 4.21 2.10 Oaxaca 1.21 3.98 -2.78
Sinaloa 3.82 2.78 1.04 Guerrero 1.43 3.70 -2.28
Jalisco 6.32 5.45 0.87 Guanajuato 2.29 4.35 -2.06
Baja California 3.08 2.29 0.79 Michoacán 1.90 3.77 -1.87
Coahuila 3.05 2.34 0.71 Veracruz 4.59 6.19 -1.60

9. Conclusion

Modern economies use intergovernmental transfers to help finance important goods and services provided by subnational governments such as education, health services, infrastructure and anti-poverty programs. The normative literature of public economics has emphasized that intergovernmental transfers should be designed to alleviate problems of regional inequality and inefficiency in the allocation of resources. The literature on optimal taxation and spending has also pointed out that resources should be allocated to the highest economic returns and therefore the regional heterogeneity of preferences of individuals for local public spending should also be a principle of policy design in intergovernmental transfers.

In this paper we develop an optimal theory of intergovernmental transfers which provides specific rules for shares of resources of intergovernmental transfers to be assigned to state governments in Mexico. Based on this theory, we develop a simulation analysis that provides estimates about the optimal shares of resources to be allocated to state governments assuming that policy makers might have objectives such as minimizing the regional inequality of income and maximizing social welfare by matching localpublic spending with the heterogeneous regional preferences of individuals.

Our analysis provides interesting insights about the regional distribution of intergovernmental transfers in Mexico: the best fit of our model to observed data suggests that policy makers could use a social welfare function that satisfies the properties of anonymity and symmetry (all states receive the same social weight in the social welfare function). Our estimates also suggest that the best predictor of the share of intergovernmental transfers is the density of population in Mexico. This has the important implication that policy makers in Mexico do not fully incorporate the heterogeneity of preferences for goods and services provided by subnational governments and the regional inequality of income in the design of intergovernmental transfers.

However, our model suggests that incorporating these objectives of policy would lead to a different allocation of intergovernmental transfers that would represent a Pareto improvement in the allocation of public resources in the Mexican economy. In this paper, we provide estimates of optimal shares of intergovernmental transfers for state governments that take into account the heterogeneity of preferences for goods and services and the regional inequality of income in the design of intergovernmental transfers.

Our analysis also represents a proposal for policy reform in the allocation of intergovernmental transfers. In this paper we have assumed that policy makers want to maximize a social welfare function and therefore this paper contributes in pointing out feasible policy reforms that could lead to Pareto improvements. However, politicians and bureaucrats (who are in charge of the design and implementation of policy) might not seek to design policy to maximize the society’s welfare but to benefit groups of interest or to maximize votes in elections. In that sense, the policy prescriptions described in this paper might not be aligned with political realities and electoral incentives. An interesting avenue for future research is to extend this analysis considering a modern political economy view that could also point out towards political feasibility in policy design.

Referencias

Atkinson, A. B. and J. E. Stiglitz (1972). "The structure of indirect taxation and economic efficiency." Journal of Public Economics 1(1): 97-119. [ Links ]

Atkinson, A. B. and J. E. Stiglitz (1976). "The design of tax structure: Direct versus indirect taxation and economic efficiency." Journal of Public Economics 6(1): 55-75. [ Links ]

Besley, T., and S. Coate. (2003). “Centralized versus decentralized provision of local public goods: a political economy approach.”, Journal of Public Economics , 87: 2611-2637 [ Links ]

Brennan, G., and Buchanan, J., (1980). “The power to tax: analytical foundations of a fiscal constitution, Cambridge; New York:Cambridge University Press. [ Links ]

Centro de Estudios de las Finanzas Publicas, (2017), “Criterios que se utilizan para la asignación presupuestal a entidades federativas y municipios en la Ley de Coordinación Fiscal”. 1-54. [ Links ]

Bahl, R., J Boex, y J. Martinez-Vazquez , (2001), “The Design and Implementation of Intergovernmental Transfers”, International Studies Program, pp:1-25. [ Links ]

Boadway, R. (2007) Intergovernmental redistributive Transfers: efficieny and equity. In: Boadway, R.A. and Shah, A., Eds., Intergovernmental Transfers, Principles and Practice, The World Bank, Washington DC, 317-338. [ Links ]

Boadway, R. and Shah, A. (2007) Intergovernmental Fiscal Transfers: Theory and Practice. The World Bank, Washington DC. [ Links ]

Caceres, R.L. and S.F. Seninger (1980). “Redes interregionales, estructuras jerarquicas y fuga de la riqueza en centroamérica: un análisis de cadena de Markov”. El Trimestre Económico Vol. 49, 195(3), 623-645. [ Links ]

Caceres, R.L. (1995), "Las disparidades nacionales y la integración subregional", Comercio Exterior Vol. 45, 99-105. [ Links ]

Ferris, J.M. (1983).Demands for public spending: An attitudinal approach. Public Choice 40: 135-154. https://doi.org/10.1007/BF00118516 [ Links ]

Hankla, C. J. Martinez-Vazquez, and R.A. Ponce Rodriguez , (2019), Local accountability and national coordination in fiscal federalism, Edward and Elgard Publishing. London, UK. [ Links ]

Hettich, Walter, and Stanley L. Winer. (2005). Democratic choice and taxation: a theoretical and empirical analysis. New York: Cambridge University Press. [ Links ]

Holsey C.M. and T. Borcherding., (1997), Why does government’s share of national income grow? An assessment of the recent literature on the U.S. experience, in Mueller D., Perspectives on Public Choice, A Handbook, Cambridge University Press. [ Links ]

Lockwood, B. 2008. Voting, lobbying and the decentralization theorem, Economics Politics, 20(3): 416-431 --. 2015. The political economy of decentralization, in: E. Ahmad, and G. Brosio (eds), Handbook of Multilevel Finance, Edward Elgar Publishing, pp. 33-60. [ Links ]

Meltzer, A. H. and Richard, S. F. (1981) "A Rational Theory of the Size of Government, " Journal of Political Economy 89: 914 - 927. [ Links ]

Ponce-Rodriguez, R.A and J.C. Medina- Guirado . (2018). Fiscal Institutions and the Size and Inter-Regional Distribution of Public Redistribution, Ensayos, Revista de Economía 37(1), 1-42. [ Links ]

Ponce-Rodriguez, R.A., C. Hankla, J., Martinez Vazquez and E. Heredia-Ortiz, (2018), Rethinking the Political Economy of Decentralization How Elections and Parties Shape the Provision of Local Public Goods, Publius: the Journal of federalism, Vol. 48, Nº. 4, 523-558. [ Links ]

Rao, M.G. (2007) Resolving Fiscal Imbalances: Issues in Tax Sharing. In: Boadway, R.A. and Shah, A., Eds., Intergo- vernmental Transfers, Principles and Practice, The World Bank, Washington DC, 317-338. [ Links ]

Saez, Emmanuel, and Stefanie Stantcheva . 2016. "Generalized Social Marginal Welfare Weights for Optimal Tax Theory." American Economic Review, 106 (1): 24-45. [ Links ]

Smart, M., (1998), “Taxation and Deadweight Loss in a System of Intergovernmental Transfers” Canadian Journal of Economics 31, pp. 189-206. [ Links ]

Ter-Minassian, T. (1997), “Fiscal Federalism in Theory and Practice”, Washington: The International Monetary Fund. [ Links ]

Theodore C. Bergstrom, Daniel L. Rubinfeld and Perry Shapiro. (1982). Micro-Based Estimates of Demand Functions for Local School Expenditures. Econometrica 50(5), 1183-1205. [ Links ]

World Bank. (2019). Mexico: Reforming Intergovernmental Transfers to More Effectively Advance Their Policy Objectives (English). Washington, D.C.: World Bank Group. [ Links ]

3A vertical fiscal imbalance corresponds to the difference between the own revenues of a particular level of government and its expenditures.

4The regional heterogeneity of preferences of individuals for local public goods determine the regional distribution of social marginal benefits from local public spending and social marginal costs from taxation that finances government spending. Thus, in the context of a federation, a government that incorporates the heterogeneity of preferences might lead to an efficient allocation of local public spending.

5This social welfare function is said to be symmetric because all households have the same marginal social utility in the social welfare function.

6It is worth mentioning that there is not a single formula for the allocation of the total amount of intergovernmental transfers due to the design of the fund of “participaciones” is different from the program of “aportaciones¨. In practice, intergovernmental transfers are used in Mexico for different purposes: for instance, the fund of “participaciones” is a revenue sharing program financed by federal taxes. According to a report from the Centro de Estudios de las Finanzas Publicas (2017), the general fund of “participaciones” uses a linear weighted formula to distribute resources to states that takes into consideration the growth of the general fund of “participaciones”, the evolution of gross domestic product of each locality over time, and the evolution of tax revenue collection over time in each locality. It is important to recall that Intergovernmental transfers can also be discretionary transfers though specific agreements or convenios to finance the perceived priorities of policy makers in the central and state governments and therefore these funds are allocated in a discretionary form.

7That is to say, the observed share of intergovernmental transfers received by Ciudad de Mexico in 2014 were 6.74% while the corresponding share of intergovernmental transfers received by Ciudad de Mexico if social weights satisfy the properties of unanimity and symmetry is 12.61%. this represents a gain of 5.87 in percentage points of the total amount of resources devoted to intergovernmental transfers.

Appendix.

Proposition 1. The optimal allocation of inter-governmental transfers to subnational government in locality i is given by

Ti*=  ΦiNiβi {i=1INiei i=1IΦiNiei}     i (A.1)

Proof.

The problem of policy design can be stated as follows:

δ=i=1IΦiNi{ei(1τ)+βiln(Ti)}+λ{τi=1INieii=1ITi}  (A.2)

Where λ is a Lagrange multiplier. The first order conditions are:

δTi=ΦiNiβiTi*λ*=0         Ti*>0 (A.3)

δτ=i=1IΦiNiei+λ*i=1INiei=0     τ*>0  (A.4)

δλ=τ*i=1INieii=1ITi*=0     λ*>0  (A.5)

Re-arrange the first order conditions to show that

Ti*=  ΦiNiβi {i=1INiei i=1IΦiNiei}     i (A.6)

Proposition 3. If the allocation of social weights is determined by equity concerns about the inter-regional distribution of income such that

Φi={eiminei         eieimin   0            ei<eimin (A.7)

Then the optimal allocation of inter-governmental transfers is denoted by TiP* such that

TiP*=Niβi{Ef(ei)ei}    i  (A.8)

And Ef(ei)=i=1Ifiei is a weighted average of per capita income in locality i, and fi is the density of population in locality i over the nationwide population such that

fi(0,1]:fi=Nii=1INi   i=1Ifi=1 (A.9)

Proof.

From proposition 1, the optimal level of inter-governmental transfers is given by:

Ti*=  ΦiNiβi {i=1INiei i=1IΦiNiei}     i (A.10)

If priorities on policy are determined social weights that reflect a concern over the inter-regional inequality of income such that

Φi={eiminei         eieimin   0            ei<eimin (A.11)

Then use Φi=eiminei i to show TiP* is given by:

TiP*=eimineiNiβi{i=1INiei i=1I{eiminei}Niei} i  (A.12)

TiP*=Niβiei{i=1INiei i=1INi} i  (A.13)

We define fi as the density of population in locality i over the nationwide population such that

fi(0,1]:fi=Nii=1INi   i=1Ifi=1 (A.14)

And define the weighted average of per capita income in locality i, by Ef(ei) , where

Ef(ei)=i=1Ifiei (A.15)

Then express TiP* as follows:

TiP*=Niβi{Ef(ei) ei} i (A.16)

Proposition 5. If the allocation of social weights is determined by an Inter-Regional Paretian distribution of preferences given by

Φi={βiβimaxβiβimax0βi>βimax

Then the optimal allocation of inter-governmental transfers is denoted by Tiβ* such that

Tiβ*=Niβi{βiEh(βi)}  i  (A.17)

Where Eh(βi)=i=1Ihi(βi) , is the nationwide weighted average of the parameter of intensity of preferences βi and

hi(ei)(0,1]:hi(ei)=Nieii=1INiei   (A.18)

Proof.

From proposition 1, the optimal level of inter-governmental transfers is given by:

Ti*=Ti*=  ΦiNiβi {i=1INiei i=1IΦiNiei}     i (A.19)

If priorities on policy are determined social weights that reflect a concern over the inter-regional distribution of preferences for local public spending such that

Φi={βiβimaxβiβimax0βi>βimax (A.20)

Then use Φi=βiEmaxβi i to show Tiβ* is given by:

Tiβ*=βiβimaxNiβi{i=1INiei i=1I{βiβimax}Niei}    i        (A.21)

Equivalent to

Tiβ*=βiNiβi{i=1INiei i=1IβiNiei}      i       (A.22)

Note that we can define hi(ei) as the share of income in locality i over the nationwide income, in the following way:

hi(ei)(0,1]:hi(ei)=Nieii=1INiei  i=1Ihi(ei)i=1  (A.23)

And define Eh(βi) as the nationwide weighted average of the parameter of intensity of preferences βi such that.

Eh(βi)=i=1Ihiβi (A.24)

Use the former condition in Tiβ*toshow :

Tiβ*=Niβi{βi Eh(βi)}      i       (A.25)

Table 5 Shares of Intergovernmental Transfers, Estimates of Simulation Analysis  

Entidad Real (Observed) Share of Intergovernmental Transfers Social Weights Considering Unanimity and Symmetry Social Weights Considering Inequality of Income Social Weights Considering Heterogeneity of Preferences
Aguascalientes 1,19 1,18 2,80 1,24
Baja California 2,29 3,08 2,93 3,08
Baja California Sur 0,80 0,74 2,89 0,81
Campeche 1,16 0,80 0,52 0,79
Coahuila 2,34 2,82 2,26 3,05
Colima 0,83 0,73 3,52 0,84
Chiapas 5,05 2,60 3,98 1,46
Chihuahua 3,10 3,15 2,92 3,03
Ciudad de México 6,74 12,61 2,09 20,12
Durango 1,80 1,33 3,11 1,14
Guanajuato 4,35 3,43 2,50 2,29
Guerrero 3,70 2,13 4,19 1,43
Hidalgo 2,49 1,97 3,71 1,53
Jalisco 5,45 6,65 2,83 6,32
Edo. de México 11,73 13,41 4,31 12,10
Michoacán 3,77 2,78 3,28 1,90
Morelos 1,54 1,60 3,93 1,51
Nayarit 1,22 1,09 4,50 1,10
Nuevo León 4,21 5,31 2,07 6,30
Oaxaca 3,98 2,07 3,74 1,21
Puebla 5,11 4,60 3,96 3,86
Querétaro 1,63 1,87 2,44 1,98
Quintana Roo 1,43 1,32 2,56 1,28
San Luis Potosí 2,25 2,11 3,02 1,83
Sinaloa 2,78 3,17 4,20 3,82
Sonora 2,62 2,90 2,53 3,26
Tabasco 2,74 1,97 1,58 1,84
Tamaulipas 2,80 3,09 2,91 3,05
Tlaxcala 1,15 0,98 4,87 0,85
Veracruz 6,19 5,72 3,27 4,59
Yucatán 1,80 1,70 3,43 1,54
Zacatecas 1,78 1,09 3,14 0,85
Average 3,33 3,14 3,31 2,85
Variance 5,02 8,84 0,83 14,78

Received: April 08, 2019; Accepted: July 13, 2019

*Universidad Autónoma de Ciudad Juárez, Av. Universidad y Av. Heroico Colegio Militar S/N Zona Chamizal C.P. 32300, Ciudad Juárez, Chihuahua, México. Phone: 6883837, email: rponce@uacj.mx.

**Universidad Autónoma de Ciudad Juárez, Av. José de Jesús Macías Delgado, Núm. 18100 | Tel. (+52) 688 2100 al 09. Ciudad Juárez, Chihuahua, México. email: alan.ponce@uacj.mx.

Creative Commons License This is an open-access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License