SciELO - Scientific Electronic Library Online

 
vol.49 número194Rendição de contas e destino da dívida pública do Governo da cidade do MéxicoPolítica governamental vs. política pública: avatares dos parques eólicos no Istmo de Tehuantepec índice de autoresíndice de assuntospesquisa de artigos
Home Pagelista alfabética de periódicos  

Serviços Personalizados

Journal

Artigo

Indicadores

Links relacionados

  • Não possue artigos similaresSimilares em SciELO

Compartilhar


Problemas del desarrollo

versão impressa ISSN 0301-7036

Prob. Des vol.49 no.194 Ciudad de México Jul./Set. 2018

https://doi.org/10.22201/iiec.20078951e.2018.194.61286 

Articles

Capital Accumulation and State Growth in Mexico: A Panel Data Analysis

Domingo Rodríguez Benavides1 

Miguel Ángel Mendoza González2 

Miguel Ángel Martínez García3 

1 Autonomous Metropolitan University, Azcapotzalco Campus, UNAM Faculty of Economics, and National Polytechnic Institute, Mexico, respectively. E-mail addresses: dorobe@correo.azc.uam.mx, mendozag@unam.mx, and mmartinezga@ipn.mx, respectively.

2 Autonomous Metropolitan University, Azcapotzalco Campus, UNAM Faculty of Economics, and National Polytechnic Institute, Mexico, respectively. E-mail addresses: dorobe@correo.azc.uam.mx, mendozag@unam.mx, and mmartinezga@ipn.mx, respectively.

3 Autonomous Metropolitan University, Azcapotzalco Campus, UNAM Faculty of Economics, and National Polytechnic Institute, Mexico, respectively. E-mail addresses: dorobe@correo.azc.uam.mx, mendozag@unam.mx, and mmartinezga@ipn.mx, respectively.


Abstract

This paper studies the link between economic growth and state industrial capital stock accumulation using panel data techniques in the time period 1960-2012. The analysis is done in two moments: the age of national industrialization (1960-1982) and the structural reform era (1983-2012). The results point to a long-term relationship in both periods, but with a sign opposite of the expected sign in the latter, suggesting that the deceleration of industrial capital can explain the slowdown over the past three decades. This result is confirmed with the decline of manufacturing, as well as other economic indicators. The causality tests demonstrate two-way causality between the two variables, evincing a virtuous cycle between growth and accumulation.

Keywords: Industrialization; economic growth; capital accumulation; investment; panel data

resumen

En el presente texto se estudia el vínculo entre el crecimiento económico y la acumulación del stock de capital industrial estatal mediante técnicas de panel, en el periodo 1960-2012. El análisis se efectúa sobre dos momentos: el de industrialización nacional (1960-1982) y el de las reformas estructurales (1983-2012). Los resultados muestran una relación de largo plazo en ambos periodos, pero con el signo opuesto al esperado en el último, lo cual sugiere que la desaceleración del capital industrial puede explicar la ralentización del crecimiento en las últimas tres décadas. Este resultado se confirma con la caída de la manufactura, así como de otros indicadores económicos. Los resultados de las pruebas de causalidad muestran bidireccionalidad entre ambas variables, evidenciando así un círculo virtuoso entre crecimiento y acumulación.

Palabras clave: industrialización; crecimiento económico; acumulación de capital; inversiones; datos de panel

Clasificación JEL: C23; C33; E22; G31; O14

Résumé

Dans le présent texte nous étudions le lien entre la croissance économique et l'accu mulation du stock de capital industriel de l'Etat par des analyses des données pour la période 1960-2012. L'analyse est réalisée à deux moments: l'industrialisation natio nale (1960-1982) et les réformes structurelles (1983-2012). Les résultats montrent une relation à long terme dans les deux périodes, mais avec le signe opposé à celui attendu dans le dernier, ce qui suggère que la décélération du capital industriel peut expliquer le ralentissement de la croissance au cours des trois dernières décennies. Ce résultat est confirmé à cause de la baisse de la fabrication, ainsi que d'autres indicateurs économiques. Les résultats des tests de causalité montrent une bidirectionnalité entre les deux variables. Ainsi un cercle vertueux entre croissance et accumulation est mis en évidence.

Mots clés: industrialisation; croissance économique; accumulation de capital; investissements; panneau des données

resumo

No presente texto, se estuda a ligação entre o crescimento econômico e a acumulação do stock de capital industrial estatal por meio de técnicas de panel no período 1960 2012. A análise é realizada em dois momentos: o período da industrialização nacional (1960-1982) e o das reformas estruturais (1983-2012). Os resultados mostram uma relação de longo prazo em ambos os períodos, mas com o sinal oposto ao esperado no último, o que sugere que a desaceleração do capital industrial pode explicar a dimi nuição da velocidade do crescimento nas últimas três décadas. Este resultado é confirmado com a queda da manufatura, assim como de outros indicadores econômicos. Os resultados dos testes de causalidade mostram a bidirecionalidade entre ambas variáveis, demonstrando assim um círculo virtuoso entre o crescimento e a acumulação.

Palavras-chave: industrialização; crescimento econômico; acumulação de capital; investimentos; dados em panel

1. INTRODUCTION

In recent decades, Mexico underwent a sharp economic policy shift in the wake of the 1982 crisis. Between the nineteen-fifties and seventies, the country was an archetype of growth and financial stability. The primary macroeconomic variables were stable, the exchange rate to the dollar was fixed, convertibility held strong with no restrictions, inflation was moderate, and the gross domestic product (GDP) per capita climbed to high growth rates (Dornbusch and Werner, 1994). This period of stability drew to a close around the time of the 1973 oil crisis with burgeoning oil prices. High revenues from oil exports had left some breathing room in the fiscal budget, which meant policies became extremely expansive, the currency was overvalued, and public debt was on the rise. All of these events brought the financial system and the exchange rate to collapse, due to capital flight, pushing Mexico to bankruptcy in 1982, at which point it had to renegotiate its debt under the painful conditions imposed by its creditors.

Mexico not only paid high interest rates, but in order to borrow the money, was forced to enact a series of economic reforms to stabilize the economy (Dornbusch and Werner, 1994). Although the 1950-1970 growth strategy did generate some distortions (Mejía and Lucatero, 2011), there is more or less consensus as to the importance of capital accumulation as a source of growth during this time period (Elías, 1992; Santaella, 1998).

Since 1982, the key structural reforms were budgetary consolidation, trade openness, free-floating prices and rates in the public sector, and financial sector liberalization (Dornbusch and Werner, 1994). On the fiscal playing field, budgetary consolidation was the cornerstone of the reform and stabilization in Mexico. Major cuts to public spending, tax reforms to expand the tax base, and the privatization of public enterprises were just some of the measures involved in this adjustment. Privatization was a key objective of the public finance reforms (Dornbusch and Werner, 1994). To control the government deficit, some of these companies were sold off to businessmen and women, while others were simply shut down.

In the commercial realm tariff rates have gradually been brought down and reined in since the mid-nineteen-eighties. The initial tariff cut was greater for consumer goods, while intermediate and capital goods saw the liberalization gradually enter into force ever since the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) took effect in 1994. Governmental price liberalization was done to correct a supposed distortion in the price structure and bring about more efficient use of production factors.

Multiple studies have attempted to explore the growth slowdown in Mexico. Ros (2008) attributes the economic slowdown in large part to poor investment performance. The inability to invest with fixed capital would seem to be the underlying cause of the country's failure to achieve sustained growth since the structural reforms were implemented in 1982. Along these same lines, FitzGerald (2007) asserted that sustainable long-term economic growth depends on the capacity to raise physical and human capital accumulation rates, make optimal use of productive assets, and guarantee the population's access to them.

In any event, the outcome of the economic policies applied in the time period 1960-1981 and then 1982-2016 are vastly divergent. It could be argued that performance in these two time periods is the result of a strong relationship among domestic industrialization, fixed capital accumulation, rapid growth, and an industrial policy with a degree of state intervention.

This paper analyzes the role played by physical capital formation in economic growth (e.g., gGDP) via the fixed capital stock (e.g., gK) with state-level information for Mexico, using different panel data techniques. The text is structured as follows: the second section is a non-exhaustive review of pertinent literature. The third section lays out the theoretical framework and analyzes the growth trajectories, as well as investment in Mexico between 1960 and 2016. The fourth section introduces the econometric methodology used, and the main results. Finally, the conclusions point to several economic policy implications.

2. LITERATURE REVIEW

The hypotheses to explain the direction of causality between fixed capital and economic growth are multiple and substantially varied, so there is no consensus as to the direction of causality between them (Mehrara and Musai, 2013). One of the propositions wielded is that stronger investment can promote economic growth. This hypothesis is grounded theoretically in the Harrod (1939) and Domar (1946) "Keynesian" growth models, and contemporary models. By contrast, the original neoclassical models and their multiple current variations (Barro and Sala-i-Martin, 1995) only have marginal theoretical underpinnings. Not only because other "production factors" are now included, but rather because most of the fixed capital accumulation was supplanted by "technical progress," which according to its proponents, is either exogenously (Solow, 1956, 1957) or endogenously (Roemer, 1990; Grossman and Helpman, 1991) generated. In broad strokes, under this approach, economic investment policies that influence the growth and productivity level drive long-term growth. In theory, gross investment impacts growth, whether by raising the physical capital stock or promoting technology (Levine and Renelt, 1992; Plossner, 1992). The second hypothesis is that economic growth is the principal source of fixed capital stock formation. Nevertheless, the theoretical framework that would back the notion that these transmission mechanisms actually happen is unclear (Mehrara and Musai, 2013), and they are rather grounded in empirical data.

Some of the empirical studies that have shown a positive correlation between investment and economic growth include Tyler (1981), with evidence from a group of 55 developing countries, in which investment and exports are the top drivers of growth. The fastest-growing countries between 1960 and 1977 were t hose in which capital formation also grew the fastest. Tyler holds that this finding is unsurprising, as it furnishes empirical support for economic development theories that assign a key role to capital formation.

Bond et al. (2010) also deal with the matter of whether investment affects the long-term productivity growth rate. They report that diverse cross-section and panel data studies have found evidence that the coefficient for relative investment has a positive impact on the level of the product per worker in the "steady state." The cross-section studies include: Mankiw et al. (1992), Levine and Renelt (1992), De Long and Summers (1991 and 1993), and Barro and Sala-i-Martin (1995). Specifically, both Levine and Renelt (1992) and De Long and Summers (1991) found evidence that the investment rate is the most systematic and statistically significant driver explaining growth. The papers that have drawn on panel data methods include Islam (1995), Caselli et al. (1996), and Bond et al. (2001).

On the "Asian miracle" spectacular and the underlying sources of growth, we have Kim and Lau (1994) and Young (1992 and 1995). Through growth accounting and the neoclassical aggregate production function, these authors found that most of these countries' rapid growth can simply be explained by mounting capital accumulation. They furthermore conclude that total productivity (technical progress or TFP) was not an important factor. This pattern was also verified by Rada and Taylor (2006, pp. 9-12) in Southern Asia, China, Southeast Asia, and the Asian tigers, where the capital stock growth exceeded economic growth. Their industrial restructuring consisted of moving into more capital-intensive industries (and not of destroying their own national industry). While labor productivity grew rapidly, "capital productivity" declined, and while the farm sector saw its share of the pie decline, industry got a bigger piece (and services, to a lesser extent). Moreover, the Rada and Taylor study looked at 12 regional groups containing 57 developing countries and countries in transition. Comparing the GDP and capital stock growth rates between 1990 and 2004, they found a "clear positive relationship between the two growth rates across all of the regions." In the "semi-industrialized" region of Latin America (including Mexico), the slow growth of 3% is to be expected, given that fixed capital accumulation grew at only 3%, approximately.

3. GROWTH, INVESTMENT, ACCUMULATION, AND THEIR TRAJECTORIES IN MEXICO

The idea of a relationship between distribution, accumulation, and growth is as old as economic theory itself. It blossomed with classic theory, especially with Ricardo, and matured with Marxist theory. But while the obvious factor to the classicists, given their background (agriculture and manufacturing), was labor force demand wage fund, in addition, to Marx, with the capitalist institution of technical change (Mateo and Lima, 2012), the other relevant factor was the capital stock spent on physical means of production (with big industry). By contrast, Keynes turned his attention to final demand, in which fixed investment is fundamental. The omission of wages, however, is recovered in "post-Keynesianism," but as a residual (e.g., Kaldor). The theoretical basis for this work rests on the fundamental Harrod-Domar ratio:

g= IK=sv=S . YK . Y

In which g is the economic growth rate (Y/Y), s is the saving rate (S/Y) or investment rate (if we suppose that S = I ), and v is the capital to product ratio ( K/Y). This equation is a function in which economic growth is determined by the fixed capital stock accumulation or growth rate (I/K=K/K). Regardless of the assumptions associated with the behavior of s and v, growth depends solely on capital accumulation. However, in the fifth section, we also do a proof in the opposing causal direction. In this regard, at the "Harrod-Domar crossroads," the post-Keynesian posture revolved around changes in the propensity to save (s) as a key adjustment factor through the government's regulating economic policy; on their side, the neoclassicists concentrated on changes in the ratio v through "automatic" variations in the relative prices of the "production factors" (K and L) via the liberal free market mechanism. The former approach has tended to be sidelined, while the latter has flourished to the point that it is now the predominant viewpoint held in the economic sciences, despite its theoretical and empirical snags (Sylos, 1995; Felipe, 1999).

As such, if PIB 0 is the gross domestic product in the time period 0 and PIB 1 is the product in period 1, the rate gPIB = ΔPIB / PIB = (PIB 1 - PIB 0 )/ PIB 0 measures economic growth. By contrast, to directly estimate the accumulation rate of I/K, we do not have the investment flow pertaining to the available stock of fixed capital, and the source of the latter only covers the "industrial sector." Nevertheless, the growth rate of this stock shall be used as a proxy: gK = ΔΚ ind I K ind = (K 1 - K 0 )l K 0 .

The period 1960-1981 is part of an age known as "stabilizing development." Over these 22 years, the government pushed an economic "regulating" policy. The public sector supplemented-but did not replace-the private sector, although it did support several development policies under the objective of the national interest of industrializing the country with more capital-intensive sectors, applicable to all domestic industry, both public and private. The fiscal, monetary, trade, etc. policies were all lined up in that direction. To do so, the government favored the profitability of domestic private investment, regulating foreign investment and supplementing with public investment in strategic, risky, unprofitable, and social sectors.

The time period 1982-2016 is known as the age of "structural reforms." Over these 35 years, practically every reform ever dreamt up or known to man was experimented with in Mexico at some time, to some extent, or to some degree of intensity. The State imposed a liberal and mercantilist policy for economic activity, aiming to replace the public sector with the private sector to an unimaginable measure.

We refer to the manufacturing rate (GDPman/GDP) as an indicator of the degree of industrialization, because it is the most dynamic sector; it includes more fixed capital-intensive realms and produces several of them. With efforts to boost domestic manufacturing, the GDPman/GDP accumulated growth of 19.5% (from 14.1% to 16.8%) at an annual average rate of 0.9% between 1960 and 1981. By contrast, with the policy supporting the transnational maquila industry and trade, as well as own manufacturing imports of inputs and capital, it declined 6.6% (from 16.8% to 15.7%) with an annual negative rate of 0.2% between 1982 and 2016. The average elasticity gGDPman/gGDP tied to this pattern indicates that during the time of "stabilizing development," for each national percentage point change, the change in manufacturing was 1.132 points (7.8/6.9); by contrast, with the "structural reforms," the elasticity declined to 0.94 (2.1/2.2).

An industrial pattern is associated with an investment rate (GFCF/GDP, private and public), because it depends on the type of asset formation, as well as whether national saving mechanisms are regulated or liberalized. During the regulated development era, this percentage built up an increase of 49.6% (from 17.7 to 26.5%), with annual growth of 1.9%. Inversely, during the reform period when investment was curbed and national savings stabilized, there is a cumulative drop of -13.5% (from 26.5% to 22.9%), with growth clocking in at -0.02% per year (0.78%, for 1983-2016). Note that the 2016 GFCF/GDP rate has still not returned to the 2008 level, and is nearly equal to overall national achievement 42 years ago, from 1975.

Moreover, the capital to product ratio should slowly follow the rapid changes in the GFCF/GDP rate, because it measures net investment accumulated per product, pursuant to the wear and tear on the average lifetime of the asset structure. This (industrial) asset intensity had a cumulative increase of 73.4% at an annual rate of 2.7% with national industrialization; but between 1982 and 2013, these changes were, respectively, 70.3% and 1.7%. The SR/SD column indicates that the annual average variation in the K/GDP intensity induced by the reforms represents only 0.63 of a point for each percentage point driven by nationalist technification. Indeed, the reforms paralyzed technical change. Nevertheless, the K/GDP “census” ratio seems to show some bias. First, even admitting its slow change, the 1980 to 1988 jump does not reflect the severity of the crisis of the nineteen-eighties, which does come through in the GFCF/GDP ratio of national accounts; second, the 1995-2013 decline does not contain the slow GFCF/GDP recovery. This point shall be dealt with in the fourth section.

Table 1 Growth, Fixed Investment, and Public Spending in Mexico, 1960-2016. 

Notes: b$:billions of pesos from 2013 to 1993. $Pesos/PO:2013 pesos per capita, PO: total population, halfway through the year. Percentage (r), of variables at current prices. "Cumulative" growth is an index (less 100) based in 1960 (*) and 1981(**); and % is the average geometric growth rate (g) of the time lapse indicated. ***Only covers 1960 to 2013, at 1993 prices.

Source: Created by the authors with data from ECLAC (for PO: http://www.eclac.cl/), Banxico (http://www.banxico.org.mx/estadisticas/) and INEGI (http://www.inegi.org.mx/sistemas/bie/); series from Germán (2005 and 2008) for K/PIB and K; updates as of 2016 by Rodríguez, Venegas and Lima (2013) for the GFCFpub/GDP and GP/GDP series).

Specifically, the State’s different behavior is confirmed with its respective investment effort. Between 1960 and 1981 (state regulation), the public sector fixed investment rate (GFCFpub/GDP) rose 97.6% at an average rate of 3.3% per year; between 1982 and 2016 (mercantile deregulation), it collapsed -61.6% with annual growth of -2.7%. In other words, while the nationalist State raised the public sector investment share from 5.4% to 10.7% of GDP, the State during the reform period cut back on investment from 10.7% to 3.4% of GDP. This reduction had a negative impact on the capital stock. First, because the public sector fixed capital stock was not renewed when the GFCFpub flow declined with the fiscal cutbacks tied to the reforms. Second, because much of the existing stock was liquidated when it was privatized, resold, or due to lack of repair. But the reformer State not only destroyed productive investment, but also, albeit to a lesser degree, cut back on the overall government’s current social spending (health, education, etc.); this can be measured with all of the relative public spending (GP/GDP, including GFCFpub/GDP) (Rodríguez, Venegas, and Lima, 2013).

How does the above affect social development? Directly. And that is because, pursuant to the Harrod-Domar relationship, we know that the product per capita depends on the capital per capital bound up in savings and technology among the population. Figure 1 (bottom) shows the spread of this ratio (GDP/PO vs. K/PO) both state- and nationwide. For the nation and the entire time period 1960-2013, we find a good linear (r) correlation of 83.6% and a determination (r2) of 69.91%. The ratio improves with a logarithmic regression (r2=79.91%). This means an initially strong relationship that dissipates post-1981. Breaking it out against the 1981 crisis, the first period (1960-1981) matches up with the time of nationalistic industrialization (r=96.5%, r2=93%), and the latter (1982-2013) with the deindustrialization entailed by the reform period (r=8.5%, r2=0.72%). Accordingly, the ratio between stronger social development and higher industrial capital per capita is robust during the age of stabilizing development, but not for the reform period. In this regard, the five states displaying the highest correlation were: State of Mexico, Jalisco, Puebla, Quintana Roo, and Campeche; those with the latest correlations were: Tabasco, Michoacán, Baja California Sur, Norte, and Sonora.

Figure 1 (top) moreover shows the state spread between growth and accumulation (gGDP vs. gK), which we will examine below. Throughout the entire period, there is a lower correlation and determination (r=30.6%, r2=9.34%). The ratio improves during the nationalist State (r=43.3%, r2=18.73%) but not for the reform period (r=-14.8%, r2=2.18%). As a result, according to Table 1, it is salient to note that the rapid economic and manufacturing growth during nationalism (gGDP=6.9% and GDPman=7.8%) are on average tied to the faster growth of accumulation (gK=9.6%). Likewise, the slow growth in the reform period (gGDP=2.2% and GDPman=2.1%) is related to lower accumulation (gK=3.9%). This result matches up with Lima (2005), who estimated the gross domestic fixed capital stock for the non-residential private sector (Cf^) with data from the national accounts and the perpetual inventory method (PIM).

Source: Created by the authors with data fromGermán-Soto, V., 2005,2008, and 2015 <https://works.bepress.com/vicente_german_soto/>

Figure 1 State Spread of Growth vs. Accumulation (gGDP vs. gK) and Product per Capita vs. Capital per Capita (GDP/PO vs. K/PO), 1960-2013  

To wrap it up, it emerges that social development (GDP/PO, Table 1) grew at an annual average speed of 3.8% during the stabilizing development time and at 0.6% in the reform period. That is to say, social welfare in the latter period only amounted to 17% (SR/SD) of the achievement in the former period. Likewise, it appears that low economic growth during this same period represents 32% of what it was in the latter (6.9/2.2), given that the structural reforms are tied to five severe crises that have cropped up over the past 35 years. Thus, the stronger economic growth and social development Mexico attained during the age of national industrialization from 1960 to 1981 is correlated with a higher accumulation rate and industrial capital per capita, which is in turn associated with a burgeoning manufacturing rate, a high saving and overall investment rate, rising technical intensity of capital, a progressive public fixed investment rate, and progressive rate of public spending. With that said, the weaker growth and development that afflicted Mexico during the reform and stabilization period of 1982-2016 is related to lower accumulation and capital per capita rates; which is in turn bound to a declining manufacturing rate, a low saving and overall investment rate, slow capital intensity, a falling fixed public investment rate, and decreasing relative public spending.

4. METHODOLOGY AND DATA

4.1 The Data

The series used in the analysis are the fixed capital stock (K) for the industrial sector (mining, manufacturing and electricity, gas, and water) and the product of the entire economy (GDP) for the 32 states of the Republic of Mexico in the time period 1960-2012, in prices from 1993. The data were taken from Germán-Soto (2005 and 2008), and their extent, quality, and review depend on the author. But, the K series could be biased. The Germán-Soto method (2008) consisted of deriving by regression the average age of the capital with data on gross fixed investment and employment to later estimate the stock of capital with the PIM. The bias could come from the data source, which is the five-year economic censuses conducted between 1960 and 2003. It is known that these censuses have inter-census comparability biases because (according to the census), some classes or sectors are simply not covered, new ones are added, or they are changed pursuant to the classifier. A non-readjusted historical series that normalizes the criteria to their original levels by census to compare them could contain biases. Moreover, since 2004, Germán-Soto has estimated K using the industrial GDP growth rates by state. We proceeded despite these limitations.

Unit Root Test

To determine the order of integration of the variables under study, we carried out the unit root test in the presence of non-frequent changes, in structural trends of single-variable time series when the break dates are unknown, as recently suggested by Harvey et al. (2013). This procedure is robust in the presence or lack of a unit root test in the underlying error process and avoids the "problem of the circular test" that frequently arises in empirical applications among tests on the parameters of the trend function and unit root tests. As such, no a priori information on the order of integration of the time series is required. The single-variable model can be described via:

yt=μ0+β0+i=1mμiDUit+i=1mβiDTit+ut (1)

ut=αut-1+vt

Where DU it = 1(t > T i ) and DT it = (t - T i )1(t > T i ) are dummies that reveal the changes in the level and the trend in the series for i = 1,..., m , where m is the number of breaks and 1(.) the indicator function. The maximum number of breaks on the test is equal to m = 2 (Harvey et al., 2013).

4.3 The Westerlund (2007) and Westerlund and Edgerton (2008)

Panel Cointegration Test with Structural Breaks

Two panel cointegration tests with structural breaks, developed by Westerlund (2006) and Westerlund and Edgerton (2008) were used, respectively. First, Westerlund proposed an LM test for the null hypothesis of cointegration, which permits multiple structural breaks, both in the level and the trend, for a cointegrated panel regression. According to that, first, the following model is estimated:

yi,t=αij+βiXi,t+ei,t,    j=1,, Mi+1 (2)

Where e i,t = r i,t + μ i,t y r it = r i,t-1 +øiμi,t, ß i is a specific slope for each unit assumed constant over time, and α ij is a specific intercept, also for each unit, subject to M i structural breaks. The null hypothesis is formulated such that the units on the panel are cointegrated, while the alternative establishes that at least for one unit, there is no cointegration. Westerlund and Edgerton (2008) propose two versions of the test, which derive from the LM unit root test, for the null hypothesis of no cointegration, whose test statistics are Z(M) and Z j (N); additional details regarding their derivation can be found in Westerlund and Edgerton (2008).

4.4 The Dumitrescu and Hurlin (2012)

Panel Heterogeneous Non-Causality Test

Dumitrescu and Hurlin (2012) developed a test in order to analyze the null hypothesis of Granger non-causality for panel data. The test is posited on the following: if x and y are two stationary variables observed for N individuals in T periods, for each individual i = 1, 2, ..., N at time t = 1, 2, ..., T, the following linear VAR model is considered:

yit=αi+k-1kγi(k)yi,t-k+k=1kβi(k)xi,t-k+εi,t (3)

With KN* and β ί = (β i (1) ,...,β i (K) )'. For simplicity, the individual effects α i are assumed to be fixed over time. Likewise, the assumption is made that the order of lags K is identical for all panel units and that it is balanced.

Dumitrescu and Hurlin (2012) propose testing the non-causality hypothesis between x and y:

H0:βi=0   i=1,,N (4)

Where ß i = (ß i (1) ,…,β i (p))'. Under the alternative hypothesis, there is causality from x to y in at least one unit:

H1:βi=0   i=1,,N1  βi0  i=N1+1, N1+2, ,N (5)

The statistic for the panel is obtained as the average of the cross-sections of the individual Wald statistics (Herrerias et al., 2013). Dumitrescu and Hurlin (2012) show that this statistic converges toward a normal distribution under the hypothesis of non-causality, when T tends to infinity first and later when N grows indefinitely. It is also possible to construct a standardized statistic ZN,THNC..

4.5 Estimating the Cointegrated Panels

There is ample literature enabling an estimate of the cointegrating vectors for cointegrated panels (Kao and Chiang, 2000; Pedroni, 1999, 2001, and 2004; Pesaran et al., 1999). The estimation method for cointegrated panels that we use is from Mark and Sul (2003).

5. EMPIRICAL RESULTS

Table 2 shows the results of the Harvey et al. (2013) test with one and two structural breaks for the capital stock (K) series and the product (GDP) series from the 32 states of the Mexican Republic between 1960 and 2012. Only in four states was the null unit root hypothesis rejected in K when the test was specified with one break and in three states when the test was done with two breaks. In the case of GDP, the hypothesis of the unit root was only rejected in three states with one break and in two with two breaks. There is therefore evidence that the majority of the series comprising the K and GDP panels possess a unit root.

Table 2 Result of the Harvey, Leybourne, and, Taylor (2013) Unit Root Tests with Structural Breaks for the Stock or Industrial Capital and GDF by State in Mexico, 1960-2012 

Note: *Denotes rejection at 5%. The Critical values for each test are -3.85 and-4.85 at 5% significante, respectively.

Source: Created by the authors.

Once the evidence for the unit root was found in the series for both panels, the next step was to inspect whether the two panels were cointegrated. Aiming to check whether the series comprising the K and state GDP panels maintain a long-term relationship, the Westerlund and Edgerton (2008) (see results in Table 3) panel cointegration test was performed.

As can be seen in Table 3, although the panel cointegration tests did use structural breaks, it is not possible to reject the null hypothesis of no cointegration among the variables in question, under any specification (no breaks, level shift, and regime shift) for the sample encompassing the entire period. On the contrary, this hypothesis was rejected in the first period into which the sample was divided (1960-1982), which matches up with the age of national industrialization, when the test was specified without change and with change of regime. It turns out that in the latter specification, the majority of the breaks happened in 1980. During the second time period for the sample (1983-2012), the reform era, it was only possible to reject the null hypothesis of no cointegration among the K and state GDP panel series when the test was specified without breaks with both test statistics. Accordingly, no long-term relationship between the K and GDP variables was found throughout the period studied, but there was indeed evidence of cointegration during the time periods into which the data were divided. Due to these results, both the estimates for the cointegrated panels and the panel causality tests employed in the rest of the analysis were carried out by periods: the national industrialization era (1960-1982) and the structural reform era (1983-2012).

Table 3 Results of the Westerlund and Edgerton (2008) Panel Cointegration Tests with and without Structural Breaks 

Source: Created by the authors.

The results of the estimates for cointegrated panels using the Mark and Sul (2003) method are summarized in Table 4. In both periods, the choice was made to do the test incorporating just one constant, one lag, and one forward. As is evident, the results of the estimates suggest that the capital stock has an influence on the GDP, at both the individual and overall levels, resulting positive and significant for nearly all of the states in the first period and even in various cases very close to or greater than the unit. By contrast, the results from the second time period show at the individual level for some states, the parameter that measures the incidence of capital stock (k) on GDP (y) turned out to be negative, further from the unit, and in some cases, not even statistically significant.

Table 4 Indivicual and Panel Estimates for y it = α i +ß i k it + u it with a constant. 

Notes: Estimates made with one lag and one forward in the model. a Controls for time effects.

Source: Crated by the authors.

Another noteworthy result emerges when comparing the magnitude of the coefficients estimated for each state between the two time periods, because only seven of the 32 states recorded a higher coefficient in the second period than in the first period. These states were: Coahuila, Colima, Chihuahua, Puebla, Querétaro, Quintana Roo, and San Luis Potosí; the rest of the states saw the magnitude of the incidence of capital stock on state GDP decline. The foregoing is moreover confirmed for the aggregate coefficient estimated, because the magnitude of the coefficients for the panel overall is higher in the first period than in the second, even under the specification controlling for the common effects of time on the estimate.

Finally, Tables 5, 6, 7, and 8 report the results of the Granger non-causality tests (Dumitrescu and Hurlin, 2012) with up to three lags (both individual and panel) applied to the first differences in capital stock and GDP for both periods being analyzed. As observed in these tables, the null hypothesis of Granger non-causality is rejected-among the first differences for both variables in both periods-for the overall panel. With that, we find evidence that the variables of the industrial capital stock (K) and the product (GDP) are simultaneously determined, spurring a virtuous cycle between them. Perhaps the main implication of these results is that they suggest the need to drive fixed capital accumulation in the industrial sector, which can be done via a return to the industrial policy of developing fixed capital formation in this sector.

Table 5 Results of the Granger Causality Test in Heterogeneous Panel Data Models Applied to Differences in the Capital Stock and GDP by Mexican State, 1960-1982 ( H0: Granger homogenous non-causality for Δk → Δy ) 

Source: Created by the authors

Table 6 Result of the Granger Causality Test in Heterogeneous Panel Data Models Applied to Differences in the Capital Stock and GDP by Mexican State. 1960-1982. (H0: Granger homogenous non-causality for Δy → Δk ) 

Source: Crated by the authors.

Table 7 Result of the Granger Causality Test in Heterogeneous Panel Data Models Applied to Differences in the Capital Stock and GDP by Mexican State. 1983-2012. (H0: Granger homogenous non-causality for Δk → Δy )  

Source: Crated by the authors.

Table 8. Result of the Granger Causality Test in Heterogeneous Panel Data Models Applied to Differences in the Capital Stock and GDP by Mexican State. 1983-2012. (H0: Granger homogenous non-causality for Δy → Δk ) 

Source: Crated by the authors.

6. CONCLUSIONS

This study involved a descriptive analysis and an econometric application of the Harrod-Domar relationship, which associates economic growth with capital accumulation. In particular, fixed capital accumulation in the industrial sector by state and its relationship to the state product was studied, as in order to understand the stagnation of the last three decades of structural reform, it was necessary to relate this era to the profound national deindustrialization that these sorts of policies brought on. In this regard, history has shown that mature national industrialization, not to mention the manufacturing industry as the motor, is essential both to elevating labor productivity and to attaining the economic growth of a successful nation (Hirschman, 1958; Kaldor, 1966; Atesoglu, 1993), and in order to generate social development, enable wage raises, mitigate inequalities, and reduce poverty.

This secret to success was borne out by the era of national developmentalism, laying the groundwork for Mexican industrialization that produced average growth of 6.9% (higher than the global average). Nevertheless, the neoliberalism of the "structural reforms" ruined the incipient industrialization, at a labor and human cost that for nationalism represents more growth with inequality, and entailed greater inequality with the reforms, and now stagnation for over 35 years (Jaimes and Matamoros, 2017, pp. 13, 14, and 25). Undoubtedly, the two industrial policies are worlds apart (Calderón and Sánchez, 2012; Moreno-Brid, 2013; Trejo, 2017; Tijerina, 2018). Specifically, the new liberal State asserted that NAFTA was "our industrial policy" (Johnson, 1998, p. 137), or that in reality, "the best industrial policy was no industrial policy" (Moreno-Brid, 2013) (by promoting only transnational maquila, foreign trade, international financing, and foreign investment). During the era of "stabilizing development," the State actively wielded public regulatory policies and pursued the national interest, relatively speaking. On the contrary, in the second time period, the State abandoned national interests in the name of industrialization.

Subsequently, analyzing the relationship between state-level GDP and the state-level industrial capital stock, using panel data techniques, it turns out that the two variables do have a unit root, and that the panel cointegration test with and without structural breaks reveals a long-term relationship in the two time periods analyzed: 1960-1982 (national industrialization) and 1983-2012 (structural reforms). The cointegrated panels therefore showed-both individually and for the panel as a whole-a positive and significant relationship between rapid growth and fixed capital accumulation during the nationalist industrialization age. By contrast, during the deindustrialization and structural reforms, that relationship was less positive (or negative) and less significant, between slow economic growth and accumulation. Nevertheless, this latter anomalous result may be due to a possible bias in the Germán-Soto (2008) estimates of the capital stock in the latter period. In short, although to a different temporal extent, industrial accumulation and growth are related.

This result matches up with the trajectories in the third section. Rapid social development (GDP/PO) of 3.8% and average economic growth of 6.9% (gGDP) during the era of nationalist industrialization (1960-1981) were correlate with burgeoning fixed industrial capital accumulation of 9.6% (gK) and rising capital per capita (K/PO). In comparison, the slow development of 0.6% and economic growth of 2.2% during the deindustrialization of the reform and stabilization period (1982-2016) are connected with slow industrial capital accumulation of 3.9% and weak capital per capita. This is related to a manufacturing rate (GDPman/GDP), which, in the former period, garnered growth of 19.5%, but plummeted -6.6% in the reform era. Moreover, in terms of average growth, manufactures rose (gGDPman), respectively, 7.8% a year against 2.1%. In other words, the reforms impeded the incipient domestic manufacturing industry.

These different investment patterns meant, in terms of the growth of the industrial capital technical intensity (K/GDP), respectively, an increase of 2.7% per year compared to 1.7%. Finally, these divergent investment and technical progress patterns are underpinned by, in part, the State's vastly different role as a public investor. Thus, the regulator State that supported national industrialization generated a public sector fixed investment rate (GFCFpub/GDP) that rose from 5.4% to 10.7% of GDP between 1960 and 1981. In that time period, Mexico grew 6.9%. Nevertheless, the State that expressly set out in its programs to reduce the share of public investment because it "distorted" the market brought the share down from 10.7% to 3.4% of GDP between 1982 and 2016. As a result, Mexico grew 2.2% a year in the second time period.

Furthermore, in the fifth section, the Granger non-causality tests revealed-both individually and for the panel as a whole-a two-way causal relationship in both time periods. This feedback between the variables in turn suggests a virtuous cycle between growth and accumulation.

In conclusion, there is a strong relationship between national industrialization, fixed capital accumulation, rapid growth, and industrial policy with a certain degree of regulation or state intervention. These stylized facts have tended to be forgotten or sidelined. Even so, they constitute in large part the successful policy that both China and the Asian Tigers have implemented at present, and which Mexico had until 1981. Essentially, industrial policy with state support is back again, even though it never really went away (Rodrik, 2010). This has been recognized by several economists and by several successful economies, and, more recently, by several international bodies (Rodrik, 2008; Hausmann, Rodrik, and Sobel, 2008).

In this regard, Rodrik (2010) claims that the true question is not whether an industrial policy should be applied but rather how. Rodrik sets out three principles: 1) first, a climate of collaboration between the government and the private sector must be fostered; 2) government incentives must be temporary and results-based; 3) any industrial policy must be designed to serve society as a whole, and not the bureaucrats who administer it or the companies on the receiving end of the economic or other benefits.

Bibliografía

Atesoglu, H. S. (1993), "Manufacturing and Economic Growth in The United States", Applied Economics, vol. 25. [ Links ]

Barro, R. J. y X. Sala-i-Martin (1995), Economic Growth, New York, Mc-Graw Hill. [ Links ]

Bond, S. R., Leblebicioglu, A. y Schiantarelli, F. (2010), "Capital Accumulation and Growth: A New Look at the Empirical Evidence", Journal of AppliedEconometrics, 25(7). [ Links ]

Calderón, C. y Sánchez, I. (2012), "Crecimiento económico y política industrial en México", Problemas del Desarrollo . Revista Latinoamericana de Economía, vol. 43, núm. 170. [ Links ]

Caselli, F., Esquivel, G. y Lefort, F. (1996), "Reopening the Convergence Debate: a New Look at Cross-Country Growth Empirics", Journal of Economic Growth , 1. [ Links ]

De Long, J. B. y Summers, L. H. (1991), "Equipment Investment and Economic Growth ", Quarterly Journal of Economics, 106. [ Links ]

______ y Summers, L. H. (1993), "How Strongly do Developing Economies Benefit from Equipment Investment?", Journal of Monetary Economics, 32. [ Links ]

Domar, E. (1946), "Capital Expansion, Rate of Growth, and Employment", Econometrica, 14. [ Links ]

Dornbusch, R. y Werner, A. (1994), "Mexico: Stabilization, Reform, and No Growth", Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1. [ Links ]

Elías, V. J. (1992), Sources of Growth. A Study of Seven Latin American Eco nomies, Fundación del Tucumán-International Center For Economic Growth , ICS Press, San Francisco. [ Links ]

Felipe, J. (1999), "Total Factor Productivity Growth in East Asia: A Critical Survey", The Journal of Development Studies, vol. 34, núm. 5. [ Links ]

FitzGerald, V. (2007), "Desarrollo financiero y crecimiento económico: una visión crítica", Principios, núm. 7. [ Links ]

Germán-Soto, V. (2005), "Generación del producto interno bruto mexicano por entidad federativa, 1940-1992", El Trimestre Económico, vol. 72(3). [ Links ]

______(2008), "El stock de capital industrial medido a través de la relación inversión-empleo: estimaciones para los estados mexicanos", Ensayos, 27(1). [ Links ]

Grossman, G. y Helpman, E. (1991), Innovation and Growth in the Global Economic, MIT Press, Cambridge. [ Links ]

Harrod, R. (1939), "An Essay in Dynamic Theory", Economic Journal, 49. [ Links ]

Harvey, D.I., Leybourne, S.J. y Taylor, A.M.R. (2013), "Testing for Unit Roots in The Possible Presence of Multiple Trend Breaks using Minimum Dickey-Fuller Statistics", Journal of Econometrics, vol. 177(2). [ Links ]

Hausmann, R., Rodrik, D. y Sobel, C. (2008), Reconfiguring Industrial Policy: a Framework with an Application to South Africa, Kennedy School of Government, Harvard University Press. [ Links ]

Herrerías, M. J., Joyeux, R. y Giradin, E. (2013), "Short-and-long Run Causality between Energy Consumption and Economic Growth: Evidence across Regions in China", Applied Energy, 112. [ Links ]

Hirschman, A. (1958), "Enfoque generalizado del desarrollo por medio de eslabonamientos, con especial referencia a los productos básicos", Trimestre Económico, vol. 1. [ Links ]

Islam, N. (1995), "Growth Empirics: a Panel Data Approach", Quarterly Journal of Economics , 110. [ Links ]

Jaimes, P. y Matamoros, G. (2017), "¿Qué sucedió con el casillero vacío del desarrollo de América Latina 30 años después?", Problemas del Desarrollo . Revista Latinoamericana de Economía, vol. 48, núm. 191. [ Links ]

Johnson, K. (1998), "Business-Government Relations in Mexico Since 1990: NAFTA, Economic Crisis, and the Reorganization of Business Interests", en R. Roett (ed.), Mexico's Private Sector: Recent History, Future Challenges, Boulder, Lynne Rienner Publishers. [ Links ]

Kaldor, N. (1966), Causes of the Slow Rate of Economic Growth of the United Kingdom: an Inaugural Lecture, Londres, Cambridge University Press. [ Links ]

Kao, C. y Chiang, M.H. (2000), "On The Estimation and Inference of a Cointegrated Regression in Panel Data", en B. Baltagi y C. Kao (eds.), Advances in Econometrics, 15, Elsevier Science. [ Links ]

Kim, J.I. y Lau, L. (1994), "The Sources of Economic Growth of the East Asian Newly Industrialized Countries", Journal of the Japanese and International Economies, vol. 8. [ Links ]

Levine, R. y Renelt, D. (1992), "A Sensitivity Analysis of Crosscountry Growth Regressions", American Economic Review, 82. [ Links ]

Lima, V. (2005), "Tasa de ganancia y la onda larga en México, 1939-2003", en memoria del V Coloquio Latinoamericano de Economistas Políticos (CD-ROM), Posgrado de la Facultad de Economía-UNAM, octubre de 2005. [ Links ]

Mark, N. y Sul, D. (2003), "Cointegration Vector Estimation by Panel dols and Long-run Money Demand", Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, University of Oxford, vol. 65, núm. 5. [ Links ]

Mateo, J.P. y Lima, V. (2012), "Aspectos metodológicos en el análisis del cambio tecnológico. Una perspectiva holista", Principios , núm. 20, Estudios de Economía Política. [ Links ]

Mehrara, M. y Musai, M. (2013), "The Causality between Capital Formation and Economic Growth in MENA Region", International Letters of Social and Humanistic Sciences, (08). [ Links ]

Mejía, R. P. y Lucatero, V. D. (2011), "Trends, Structural Breaks and Economic Growth n Regimes in The States of Mexico, 1940-2006", Paradigma Económico, año 3, núm. 1. [ Links ]

Moreno-Brid, J.C. (2013), "Industrial Policy: A Missing Link in Mexico's Quest for Export-led Growth", Latin American Policy, vol. 4, núm. 2. [ Links ]

Pedroni, P. (1999), "Critical Values for Cointegration Tests in Heterogeneous Panels with Multiple Regressors", Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, S1, 61. [ Links ]

______(2001), "Purchasing Power Parity Tests in Cointegrated Panels", Review of Economics and Statistics, 83. [ Links ]

______(2004), "Panel Cointegration. Asymptotic and Finite Sample Properties of Pooled Time Series Tests with an Application to the PPP Hypothesis", Econometric Theory, 20. [ Links ]

Pesaran, M. H., Shin, Y. y Smith, R. (1999), "Pooled Mean Group Estimation of Dynamic Heterogeneous Panels", Journal of the American Statistical Association, 94. [ Links ]

Plossner, C. (1992), The Search for Growth in Policies for Long-run Economic Growth , Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, Kansas City, MO. [ Links ]

Rada, C. y Taylor, L. (2006), "Developing and Transition Economies in the Late 20th Century: Diverging Growth Rates, Economic Structures, and Sources of Demand", Economic & Social Affairs, desa Working Paper No. 34. [ Links ]

Rodríguez, D., Venegas, F. y Lima, V. (2013), "La ley de Wagner versus la hipótesis keynesiana: el caso de México, 1950-2009", Investigación Económica, vol. LXXII, núm. 283. [ Links ]

Rodrik, D. (2008), One Economy, Many Recipes: Globalization, Institutions and Economic Growth , USA, Princeton University Press. [ Links ]

______(2010), "The Return of Industrial Policy", Project Syndicate, April 12, available at <http://www.project-syndicate.org/commentary/the-return-of-industrial-policy> (accessed April 3, 2013). [ Links ]

Roemer, P. (1990), "Endogenous Technological Change", Journal of Economic, núm. 98. [ Links ]

Ros, J. (2008), "La desaceleración del crecimiento económico en México desde 1982", El Trimestre Económico , vol. 75, núm. 299, México, FCE. [ Links ]

Santaella, J. (1998), "El crecimiento económico de México: explorando causas de su caída secular", Gaceta de Economía, vol. 3, núm. 6. [ Links ]

Solow, R. (1956), "A Contribution to the Theory of Economic Growth ", Quarterly Journal of Economics , 70. [ Links ]

______(1957), "Technical Change and the Aggregate Production Function", Review of Economics and Statistics, núm. 39. [ Links ]

Sylos, L.P. (1995), "Why the Interpretation of the Cobb-Douglas Production Function Must be Radically Changed", Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, vol. 6. [ Links ]

Tijerina, W (2018), "Desarrollismo subnacional para el nuevo siglo",Problemas del Desarrollo . Revista Latinoamericana de Economía, vol. 49, núm. 192. [ Links ]

Trejo, A. (2017), "Crecimiento económico e industrialización en la Agenda 2030: perspectivas para México",Problemas del Desarrollo . Revista Latinoamericana de Economía, vol. 48, núm. 188. [ Links ]

Tyler, W (1981), "Growth and Export Expansion in Developing Countries: Some Empirical Evidence", Journal of Development Economics, 9. [ Links ]

UNCTAD (2007), "Rethinking Industrial Policy", United Nations Conference on Trade and Development, Discussion Papers, núm. 183, New York. [ Links ]

Young, A. (1992), "A Tale of Two Cities: Factor Accumulation and Technical Change in Hong Kong and Singapore", NBER, Macroeconomics Annual 1992. [ Links ]

______(1995), "The Tyranny of Numbers: Confronting The Statistical Realties of the East Asian Growth Experience", Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 110. [ Links ]

Received: June 20, 2017; Accepted: January 15, 2018

Creative Commons License Este es un artículo publicado en acceso abierto bajo una licencia Creative Commons